The "Little Davis-Bacon" Acts and State Prevailing Wage Standards

CRS Report for Congress
The “Little Davis-Bacon” Acts and State
Prevailing Wage Standards
William G. Whittaker
Specialist in Labor Economics
Domestic Social Policy Division
Summary
Through the past century, many states have adopted (and, sometimes repealed)
protective statutes which, inter alia, have required contractors doing work for a state to
observe basic labor standards: notably, payment of not less than the locally prevailing
wage. Varying from one statute and jurisdiction to another, these laws are intended to
stabilize both the earnings of workers and the general structure of industry.
In 1931, the federal government followed in the same path, adopting the Davis-
Bacon Act which affects federal contract construction in much the same way the “Little
Davis-Bacon” acts affect contract construction undertaken for the states. This report
introduces the state prevailing wage laws and provides an inventory of states in which,
to varying degrees, they are in effect. It will be updated annually.
Development of Prevailing Wage Standards
Responding both to the perception of irregularities within public contracting and of
abuse of workers engaged in public work, many states have adopted statutes that are
intended to help stabilize the industry, protect workers, and bring order to the public
contracting process. These state statutes provided a foundation from which the authors
of the federal Davis-Bacon Act would draw. In some respects, they continue to provide
a laboratory in which prevailing wage policies are tested. The pros and cons of such labor
standards requirements — Are they still needed? Are they inflationary? Can they be
fairly enforced?, etc. — continue to be debated both at the state and federal levels.
“The development of State prevailing wage acts,” observed University of Wisconsin
economist David Johnson, “can be divided into two periods: pre- and post-Davis-Bacon.”
In 1891, Kansas adopted the first state statute designed to preserve prevailing labor
standards in state contract work. Other states followed suit and, before 1931, six states


Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress

States with prevailing wage laws prior to 1931had adopted legislation dealing withthis issue. They tended to focus
included: Kansas (1891), New York (1897),upon hours of work, per diem wages
Idaho (1911), Arizona (1912), New Jerseyand, to a larger degree than later
(1913), and Massachusetts (1914).enactments, upon the fair treatment
of workers. For laws passed after
1931, however, there appears to have been a greater emphasis upon the stabilization of
industry and of the community — an outgrowth of The Depression.1
The architects of the Davis-Bacon Act (1931) pointed to internal industry problems:
to itinerant contractors from beyond the area of construction, often dubbed fly-by-night
firms. Such contractors, it was charged, carried with them a crew of low-wage non-
resident labor that worked under adverse conditions — and, in that manner, competed
unfairly with local companies and retarded the economic recovery in a targeted locality.2
Federal contracting policy of that period required that public contracts be awarded to the
lowest responsible bidder — with “responsible” narrowly defined.3 After 1931, Johnson
concludes, state prevailing wage laws “had their origins in the depression and were
designed to protect labor standards from cost cutting pressures attendant upon competitive
bidding.” They were far more than just labor-protective measures however.4
State prevailing wage statutes differ from each other and, for the most part, from the
federal Davis-Bacon Act. Some of the early laws have been repealed (or have been found
unconstitutional); some have been replaced in modified form. Coverage varies widely
— from a broad generic concept of public works, to narrow application to a segment of
public work: for example, to highways or to school facilities. Dollar volume thresholds
for coverage also differ from state-to-state. Some state acts apply to general contractors;
others, to sub-contractors as well. Not all craft and skill classifications are treated in
precisely the same manner. Concepts (“locality” or “prevailing wage,” for example)
differ among the statutes as to their enforcement and record-keeping requirements. Where
state prevailing wage laws are in place, they operate alongside the federal Davis-Bacon


1 On the early prevailing wage statutes, see David B. Johnson, “Prevailing Wage Legislation in
the States,” Monthly Labor Review, Aug. 1961, p. 840. (Hereafter cited as Johnson, Prevailing
Wage Legislation.) While state statutes shared certain similarities, they were also widely diverse,
both in detail and thrust.
2 See CRS Report 94-408, The Davis-Bacon Act: Institutional Evolution and Public Policy, by
William G. Whittaker. Though early versions of the Davis-Bacon legislation had been
introduced in the late 1920s, the 1931 measure was presented as an emergency anti-Depression
bill and was strongly backed by the Hoover Administration.
3 During the 1920s and 1930s, industry had become concerned about unfair competition from
firms it regarded as irresponsible and unable to make good on contract commitments. Some
firms, it was alleged, would bid low and, once awarded a federal contract, would shop for sub-
contractors who, in the depressed state of the general economy, were willing to accept work (and
to provide workers) at progressively lower rates. See, for example G. F. Schlesinger,
“Responsibility as a Pre-Requisite,” The Constructor, Aug. 1928, pp. 24-25, 55-61; A. E. Horst,
“Accomplishments in Cooperation: Elimination of Irresponsibility Marks Progress of the
Industry,” The Constructor, Nov. 1929, pp. 28-30, 56; and E. A. St. John, “Cooperation
Eliminating Irresponsibility,” The Constructor, Apr. 1930, pp. 35-36.
4 Johnson, Prevailing Wage Legislation, pp. 840 and 842.

Act. To the extent that coverage (state and federal) may overlap, the higher standard
normally prevails.5
Impacts of State Prevailing Wage Laws
As with the federal Davis-Bacon Act, the “Little Davis-Bacon” acts have been a6
focus of controversy. Critics argue, among other things, that they are burdensome for
employers, costly to enforce, inflate the cost of construction, and are basically
unnecessary with the Fair Labor Standards (minimum wage) Act of 1938 in place.
Defenders of the acts contend that they serve to stabilize the construction industry, protect
workers (and the industry) from cutthroat employers, promote skills transfer through
apprenticeship training, and have increasingly opened new fields to minority and women
workers. Defenders would argue that the prevailing wage requirements help to assure a
higher quality of public work (given the often low-bid mandate in public contracting); but,
critics argue that private sector construction is every bit as good as public construction —
even though the prevailing wage statutes do not apply to the private sector. The debate
is circular with counter arguments for each assertion, pro and con.
Armand Thieblot, a Maryland-based management specialist and longtime critic of
prevailing wage statutes, argues that the absence of such statutes “has little effect on
unionization in the industry or on individuals’ wages.” He notes that in the private
construction market where prevailing wage laws are not an issue, “union contractors not
only are able to participate, but remain the major force in such sectors of construction as
large office buildings and major industrial construction.” He concedes, however, that a
wage differential between union and open shop firms “has undoubtedly cut into their [the
union firm’s] market share.” He affirms, however, that states without a prevailing wage
law still manage “to retain adequate construction work forces.” Thieblot concludes:
All state prevailing wage laws subject contractors to risks and to the possibility of
civil or criminal prosecution for carrying out their businesses in ways which are
perfectly acceptable to all other purchasers of construction except governments and
government agencies. All of them tend to make buildings and projects more
expensive and give governments less value for their construction dollar than a private
person would receive. All of them tend to use the contracting mechanism as a hidden
conduit for income transfers from taxpayers to construction workers.


5 In general, see Little Davis-Bacon Acts: State of the States, Washington, Center to Protect
Worker’s Rights, 1979; and Armand J. Thieblot’s compilation and analysis in Prevailing Wage
Legislation: The Davis-Bacon Act, State “Little Davis-Bacon” Acts, the Walsh-Healey Act, and
the Service Contract Act (Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press, 1986). The Wage and
Hour Division, U.S. Department of Labor, maintains an updated catalogue of these statutes.
6 Efforts to repeal the prevailing wage statutes (some successful, others not) have taken place in
a number of states during recent decades. See, for example Mark Erlich, Labor at the Ballot Box:
The Massachusetts Prevailing Wage Campaign of 1988 (Philadelphia: Temple University Press,
1990). See also Janice Fine, “Organizing for Prevailing Wage in Florida,” Labor Research
Review, fall 1988, pp. 70-79; and Jeff Vincent, “Indiana’s Prevailing Wage Law: A Preliminary
Evaluation of Its Impact on the State Construction Industry,” Labor Studies Journal, fall 1990,
pp. 17-31.

Thieblot, who has appeared before committees of the Congress in opposition to the Davis-
Bacon Act, counsels that by interfering with the free market, prevailing wage laws “insure
that wage inflation in the construction industry will outpace that in other fields.”7
Others argue fervently in support of such legislation. Peter Philips and a team from
the University of Utah have investigated the implications of repealing the “Little Davis-
Bacon” acts and have come to conclusions different from those of Professor Thieblot.
Whether prevailing wage laws are wise public policy can be disputed; but, “the original
purpose” of such legislation was not to find the cheapest possible labor but, rather, to
sustain local standards: “to prevent the government from hiring labor at below-standard
rates.” Repeal, they found (using Utah as a case study), resulted in lowered construction
wages — but also in a loss of tax revenues and increasing project cost overruns. These,
they explain, are part of the “hidden cost” of the repeal of prevailing wage laws.
In Utah, cost overruns resulted from an over-heated bidding process in which
contractors, shaved their bids in an urgent effort to obtain government contracts.
After the repeal, winning bids on state jobs came in lower than ever before .... Having
underbid jobs, contractors and subcontractors would arrange change orders to get the
jobs done or simply walk away from badly underbid jobs and leave the state to pick8
up the pieces.
Such irresponsible practices had been an industry concern in the late 1920s and seem to
have contributed to enactment of Davis-Bacon.9 In addition, the Utah team pointed to
such issues as a “less-skilled labor force” because of reduced training opportunities in the
absence of Davis-Bacon or “Little Davis-Bacon” requirements — with subsequent skills
and manpower shortages. They refer as well to “[s]lowed economic gains by minority
workers,” and to increased work-related injury rates. “The construction industry is
turbulent,” they state, and characterized by “a perennial boom-bust cycle” with “fleeting
relationships.” They conclude:
... the construction labor market has traditionally been tempered by prevailing wage
legislation and labor unions. Absent these institutions, it is unclear how — or whether
— the market will regularly and carefully train workers, or assure safety and health
on the job site, or provide training opportunities for minority workers, or offer the
incomes needed to make construction an attractive career.
These hidden costs — “loss of human capital and career jobs in this industry” — they
observe, do not appear as an entry in “the ledgers of any single contractor.” But, if not
part of a project’s direct cost, they argue, they are costs nonetheless.10


7 Armand J., Thieblot, Jr., “Prevailing Wage Laws of the States,” Government Union Review, fall

1983, pp. 62-65.


8 Peter Philips, Garth Mangum, Norm Waitzman, and Anne Yeagle, Losing Ground: Lessons
from the Repeal of Nine “little Davis-Bacon” Acts, Working Paper, Economics Department,
University of Utah, February 1995, pp 68.-69. (Hereafter cited as Philips, et al., Losing Ground.)
9 See, for example “When Low Bids Are Too Expensive,” The Constructor, Feb. 1930, pp. 40-41,

58.


10 Philips, et al, Losing Ground, pp. 68-76. See also Hamid Azari-Rad, Anne Yeagle, and Peter
(continued...)

Table 1. State Prevailing Wage Laws
Has a prevailingDoes not have a
Statewage lawprevailing wage lawCurrent status
AlabamaxRepealed in 1980
Al a s k a x
ArizonaxInvalidated by 1980 court
decision; repealed in
referendum in 1984
Ar ka nsa s x
Califo r ni a x
ColoradoxRepealed in 1985
Connecticutx
Delaware x
FloridaxRepealed in 1979
Geo r gia x
Hawa ii x
IdahoxRepealed in 1985
I llino is x
Indiana x
Iowa x
KansasxRepealed in 1987
K e nt uc ky x
LouisianaxRepealed in 1988
Maine x
Maryland x
M a ssa c huse t t s x
Michigan x
M i nne so t a x
M i ssissip p i x
M i sso ur i x


10 (...continued)
Philips, “The Effects of the Repeal of Utah’s Prevailing Wage Law on the Labor Market in
Construction,” in Sheldon Friedman, et al., (eds.), Restoring the Promise of American Labor Law
(Ithaca: Cornell University Press, 1994), pp. 207-222.

Has a prevailingDoes not have a
Statewage lawprevailing wage lawCurrent status
Montana x
Neb r aska x
Neva d a x
New HampshirexRepealed in 1985
New Jerseyx
New Mexicox
New Yorkx
North Carolinax
North Dakotax
Ohio x
OklahomaxInvalidated by 1995 court
decision
Orego n x
P e nnsyl va ni a x
Rhode Islandx
South Carolinax
South Dakotax
T e nne sse e x
Texas x
UtahxRepealed in 1981
Vermo nt x
Vir ginia x
W a shi ngt o n x
West Virginiax
W i sc o nsin x
Wyoming x
Source: Wage and Hour Division, Employment Standards Administration, U.S. Department of Labor. See
[ h t t p : / / www. d o l . g o v / e s a / we l c o me . h t m l ] .