The Magnitude of Changes That Would Be Required to Balance the FY2009 Budget

The Magnitude of Changes That Would Be
Required to Balance the FY2009 Budget
Marc Labonte
Specialist in Macroeconomics
Government and Finance Division
Summary
A balanced federal budget is a bipartisan goal of many Members of Congress. In
addition, moving the budget closer to balance is a long-term necessity because the
national debt cannot grow as a percentage of GDP indefinitely, as it would under current
policy. The budget deficit in FY2009 is projected to be between $198 billion and $407
billion. Mathematically, the budget could be balanced by reducing total spending by

7%-14%, or mandatory spending by 11%-24%, or discretionary spending by 17%-32%,


or non-military discretionary spending by 36%-72%, or by raising income tax rates by
14%-31%, or some combination of these options. The budget is unlikely to return to
balance “on its own,” as some have suggested, because higher growth rates should be
incorporated in the projections; research suggests that the revenue estimates of tax cuts
are unlikely to be significantly overstated; and the decline in the deficit found in the
CBO baseline or President’s budget rests on assumptions that differ substantially from
what is typically thought of as current policy. This report assumes a familiarity with
basic budgetary terms and concepts and will be updated as events warrant.
Many Members of Congress of both parties support the goal of a balanced budget.
In addition, moving the budget closer to balance is a long-term necessity because the
projected deficits would cause the national debt to grow indefinitely as a percentage of
GDP.1 If this occurred, it would eventually result in financial insolvency. This report lays
out generic scenarios for balancing the budget in the next fiscal year. Although these are
not policy options that are likely to be enacted, they are meant to offer simple examples
to gauge the scope of tradeoffs that would be required if policymakers eventually decide
to bring the budget back to balance. If changes are postponed or stretched over a longer
time period, they would need to be larger because of higher debt service. (CRS does not
take policy positions on the appropriate time frame for balancing the budget.)
Under the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) baseline of current policy, the
FY2009 budget deficit is projected to be $198 billion. In the Administration’s budget
proposal, the deficit would be $407 billion. However, these estimates are unlikely to


1 See Congressional Budget Office, Long Term Budget Outlook, December 2007.

match actual outcomes for a number of reasons. CBO is required to assume that
discretionary spending would grow at the rate of inflation and all expiring tax provisions
(including the alternative minimum tax) would not be renewed, and to include only
supplemental spending for military operations in Iraq that has already been enacted. The
baseline is not meant to offer a “best guess” of future policy. The Administration’s
budget proposal depends on congressional enactment and Congress may have other
priorities. Even congressional resolutions often turn out to be different from actual
results. For example, the actual budget deficit in FY2003 was $27 billion higher than
called for in the conference budget resolution. Keeping these qualifications in mind, the
actual deficit, absent policy changes and projection errors, is likely to be closer to the
Administration’s budget than CBO’s baseline since the Administration includes the
supplemental spending necessary to maintain military operations in Iraq and Afghanistan
and extends some of the expiring tax provisions in 2009. The Administration’s budget
also includes the cost of the stimulus package (P.L. 110-185), which was enacted after
CBO’s baseline was released.
The deficit can be eliminated through higher tax revenue, lower spending, or some
combination of the two. Using the CBO baseline and the Administration’s budget, this
report quantifies the scope of changes required to balance the budget through the
following options:
!reduce total spending
!reduce mandatory spending
!reduce discretionary spending
!reduce non-military discretionary spending
!raise individual income tax rates
!reduce tax expenditures
!raise individual income tax rates and reduce spending equally
Spending Reductions
Rather than single out any specific spending area to bear a disproportionate burden
of the reductions, one option would be to spread deficit reduction evenly across all policy
areas by $190 billion under the CBO baseline or $390 billion under the Administration’s
budget.2 (All policy options are smaller than the deficit because of the resulting reduction
in debt service caused by the balanced budget.) Under this option, total non-interest
spending would decrease by 7% from the CBO baseline and 14% from the
Administration’s budget.
About two-fifths of total spending (excluding net interest) is discretionary spending
(i.e., spending specifically appropriated by Congress) and three-fifths is mandatory
spending. Medicare, Social Security, and other retirement programs account for about
two-thirds of mandatory spending, and income support programs account for another one-


2 Researchers have singled out specific policy options for reducing the deficit that they think
would be desirable. See, for example, Chris Edwards, “Downsizing the Federal Government,”
Cato Institute Policy Analysis No. 515, June 2004 and Alice Rivlin and Isabel Sawhill, eds.,
Restoring Fiscal Sanity: How to Balance the Budget (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution
Press, 2004); Congressional Budget Office, Budget Options, February 2007.

sixth. To balance the budget solely through reductions in mandatory spending would
require reductions of 11% from the CBO baseline and 24% from the Administration’s
budget. If the deficit were eliminated solely through reductions in discretionary spending,
it would need to be reduced by 17% from the CBO baseline and 32% from the
Administration’s budget.
Discretionary spending is split about evenly between military and non-military
spending. Given current military operations abroad and political support for military
spending, some policymakers would prefer to limit spending reductions to non-military
discretionary spending. Non-military discretionary spending is spread across many policy
areas; education and transportation are the largest. If the deficit were eliminated solely
through reductions in non-military discretionary spending, it would need to be reduced
by 36% from the CBO baseline and 72% from the Administration’s budget.
Tax Increases
Tax increases could take many different forms and be pursued through many
different parts of the tax system. One approach might be an across-the-board increase in
marginal individual income tax rates. To balance the budget, average effective individual
income tax rates would need to be increased by 14% (i.e., from 13.2% to 15.1%3) under
the CBO baseline or 18% under the Administration’s budget. An approximately
equivalent increase in all marginal income tax rates would be needed to raise average tax
rates to that extent, assuming no behavioral responses. Because of interactions with the
alternative minimum tax, non-refundable tax credits, and so on, marginal tax rates would
probably need to be raised by a greater extent to actually achieve a 14%-31% increase in
average effective tax rates.4
To raise revenue, economists often favor reforms that broaden the tax base rather
than raise marginal tax rates.5 Under a theoretically “ideal” income tax system, the tax
treatment of all net income would be the same, regardless of how it is earned or spent.
In our current tax structure, tax expenditures (deductions, exemptions, and credits) give
special preferences to certain types of economic behavior. While it is beyond the scope
of this report to evaluate the effect on efficiency of any particular tax expenditure, it is
useful to consider how much revenue could be generated by broadening the base as an
alternative to raising marginal tax rates. For example, eliminating only the five largest
tax expenditures, which include the exclusion for health insurance premiums and
deduction for home mortgage interest, would raise more than enough revenue under the
Administration’s budget to balance the budget without any increase in marginal rates.6


3 See CBO, The Budget and Economic Outlook, January 2008, Table 4-2.
4 Some policymakers have argued that the fiscal position should be improved by repealing the tax
cuts of 2001, 2003, and 2004. According to revenue estimates by the Joint Tax Committee, this
policy would reduce the Administration’s budget deficit by about half in 2009.
5 The Tax Reform Act of 1986 (P.L.99-514) is a prominent example of an act that broadened the
tax base and increased tax revenues (at least initially) — despite reducing marginal tax rates.
6 Based on OMB estimates of the revenue lost to tax expenditures in 2009 relative to an ideal tax
system. This can be considered only a rough estimate because if different tax expenditures were
(continued...)

The large sums involved in the previous examples suggest that some might find it
desirable to balance the budget through a combination of tax increases and spending cuts.
One option would be to split the revenue difference evenly between overall spending cuts
and individual income tax increases. This solution would require a 3% decrease in total
spending and a 7% increase in average effective tax rates under the CBO baseline, and a
7% decrease in total spending and a 16% increase in average effective tax rates under the
Administration’s budget. These options, and those previously discussed, are summarized
in Table 1.
Table 1. Summary of Selected Policy Options to Balance
the Budget in 2009
Policy OptionPercent decrease in spending/increase intaxes from:
CBO baselineAdministration’s
budget
Reduce total spending7%14%
Reduce mandatory spending11%24%
Reduce discretionary spending17%32%
Reduce non-military discretionary spending36%72%
Raise individual income taxes14%31%
Raise individual income taxes and reducespending: 3%spending: 7%
spending equallytaxes: 7%taxes: 16%
Source: CRS calculations based on CBO and OMB projections.
Will the Budget Deficit Go Away on Its Own?
Some commentators have argued that the drastic policy changes illustrated above
will not be necessary because the budget deficit will shrink on its own. They make a
number of arguments to support this claim.
First, they point to the improvement in the deficit that occurs over time in the CBO
baseline and the President’s budget proposal. Both the CBO baseline and the
Administration’s budget move back to surplus beginning in 2012. It is accurate to
characterize these projections as requiring significant changes from what is typically
considered current policy, however. The CBO baseline assumes discretionary spending
will decline 1.5 percentage points to 6.1% of GDP in 2018; discretionary spending has
never been this low since World War II. (Put differently, discretionary spending would
grow by one-third the rate it has grown in the last 10 years.) The CBO baseline also


6 (...continued)
simultaneously reduced, there would be interactions between them that could be higher or lower
than the cost of reducing them separately. For examples, see Leonard Berman, “Is the Tax
Expenditure Concept Still Relevant?” National Tax Journal, September 2003, p. 615.

assumes that many taxpayers will fall under the AMT and all expiring tax provisions will
not be renewed, including the 2001 and 2003 tax cuts. The President’s FY2009 budget
proposal assumes that there will be no spending on operations in Iraq and Afghanistan
after 2009, AMT relief will be allowed to expire after 2009, and discretionary spending
will fall to its lowest post-World War II level by 2012. If CBO’s or the Administration’s
assumptions are altered, the deficit increases over the next 10 years.7
Second, it is argued that faster economic growth will lead to higher revenues than
predicted, similar to the experience of the late 1990s. It is true that actual growth was
higher than projected in the late 1990s, and this, in turn, caused revenues to be higher than
projected. But economic growth in this decade has not matched the higher growth of the

1990s. For example, growth exceeded 3% in seven years from 1992 to 2000. Since 2001,


economic growth has exceeded 3% only twice.
The unexpectedly rapid increase in revenue from capital gains realizations was
another important element of the “revenue surprise” of the late 1990s. Capital gains
revenues rose from $54 billion in 1996 to $119 billion in 2000, but then fell, following
the stock market crash, to a estimated $50 billion in 2003. Capital gains revenues made
a strong recovery to $122 billion in 2007, so there are unlikely to be further positive
surprises in the future.
It should also be noted that the improvement in the budget balance in the 1990s was
not just good fortune, but also the result of underlying budgetary decisions. To achieve
budget balance, taxes were raised in 1990 (P.L.101-508) and 1993 (P.L.103-66) and
spending was reduced from 22.3% of GDP in 1991 to 18.4% of GDP in 2000. The largest
reduction in spending was defense spending in response to the end of the Cold War.
Defense spending fell from 6.2% of GDP in 1986 to 4.6% of GDP in 1991 to 3.0% of
GDP in 2000. Spending on non-defense discretionary, Social Security, and interest
payments on the debt (because the debt was declining) also fell as a percentage of GDP
between 1991 and 2000. Since 2000, spending has risen as a percentage of GDP to an
estimated 20.4% in 2006. It fell to 20.0% of GDP in 2007.
Third, it is argued that the deficit projections are based on faulty assumptions that
overestimate the cost of tax cuts because they do not include “feedback effects.” It is
claimed that, in reality, the tax cuts will cost much less than originally projected because
tax cuts spur higher growth, thereby “paying for themselves,” at least in part. (The
revenue-raising options laid out in this report also assume there will be no feedback
effects.) Based on existing theory and empirical evidence, CBO and the Joint Committee
on Taxation (JCT) have provided alternative estimates of how much the 2003 tax cuts will
cost after allowing for feedback effects on GDP. Assuming that the Federal Reserve does
not let inflation rise, JCT found that the tax cuts could cost 5.8%-16.1% less in the first
five years, and 2.6%-11.8% less in the next five years. CBO found that the cost of the
President’s 2004 budget proposals could be between 29% lower and 10% higher over the
first five years, and between 17% lower and 15% higher over the next five years.8 This


7 See CRS Report RL31414, Baseline Budget Projections: A Discussion of Issues, by Marc
Labonte.
8 Congressional Budget Office, An Analysis of the President’s Budgetary Proposals for FY2004,
(continued...)

indicates that, under the best case scenario, the feedback effects of the tax cuts would not
generate enough revenues to move the budget significantly closer to balance and, under
the worst case scenario, could increase the budget deficit more than under “static” revenue
estimates. It should also be noted that, to date, there is no evidence that the tax cuts have
resulted in less revenue loss than originally projected. After adjusting for economic
conditions and temporary factors, revenues have fallen by more than the original “budget
scores” for the tax cuts had indicated.9
Fourth, it is argued that budget projections are highly uncertain, and may prove to
be too pessimistic. This is true: the degree of uncertainty surrounding budget projections
dwarfs the projected deficits in the out years of the projections. For example, CBO
estimates there is a 25% chance that there will be a deficit of at least 0.3% of GDP under
the baseline in 2009 — and a 25% chance that the deficit will be at least 2.3% of GDP.10
This means that the permanency of the deficits now projected is far from being a “sure
thing.” But while the projections may prove to be too pessimistic, it is equally likely that
the projections are too optimistic. Although projections made today will certainly prove
to be incorrect, the probability that the budget deficit will turn out to be higher than
predicted is equal to the probability that it will turn out to be lower than predicted.
The Burden of the Status Quo
Many would consider the policy options laid out in this report to be too burdensome
to be feasible. But in mainstream economics, a budget deficit imposes a burden that is
just as real as higher taxes or spending cuts. Deficits can be financed only by borrowing
real resources. When these resources are borrowed out of American saving, the budget
deficit pushes up interest rates and “crowds out” private investment spending that is
necessary to increase future standards of living. In effect, this outcome shifts the burden
of the deficit to future generations by causing future living standards to be lower than they
otherwise would be. When the resources are borrowed from foreigners, the trade deficit
widens and foreigners, rather than Americans, enjoy the returns from that borrowing.
Balancing the budget shifts a burden, but it does not create one.11


8 (...continued)
March 2004; Congressional Budget Office, How CBO Analyzed the Macroeconomic Effects of
the President’s Budget, July 2003; Joint Committee on Taxation, “Macroeconomic Analysis of
H.R.2,” Congressional Record, Doc 2003-11771, May 8, 2003. For a discussion, see CRS Report
RL31949, Issues in Dynamic Revenue Estimating, by Jane Gravelle.
9 See CRS Report RS22550, The Federal Budget: Sources of the Movement From Surplus to
Deficit, By Marc Labonte.
10 See Congressional Budget Office, The Uncertainty of Budget Projections, March 2007.
11 See CRS Report RL30520, The National Debt: Who Bears Its Burden? by Marc Labonte and
Gail Makinen. A trade deficit is the necessary result of borrowing abroad because borrowing can
only occur if Americans spend more abroad than foreigners spend on American goods.