Market-Based Environmental Management: Issues in Implementation

CRS Report for Congress
Market-Based
Environmental Management:
Issues in Implementation
March 7, 1994
John L. Moore and John E. Blodgett, Coordinators
Claudia Copeland, David E. Gushee, Susan L. Mayer, James E.
McCarthy, and Larry B. Parker
Environment and Natural Resources Policy Division
Congressional Research Service ˜ The Library of Congress
View Page Image


MARKET-BASED ENVIRONMENTAL MANAGEMENT:
ISSUES IN IMPLEMENTATION
SUMMARY
The acid rain title of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments authorizes the first nationwide
system for trading the regional location and method of pollution control. This market-type
mechanism, if successfully implemented, could reduce the cost of compliance of meeting new
limits on sulfur dioxide emissions, the main precursor of acid rain.
Successful passage of the sulfur dioxide trading mechanism has invigorated efforts to add
similar mechanisms to the regulatory regimes for other environmental management areas.
Limitations of current regulatory approaches, complexity of remaining and emerging
environmental problems, and the attack on the Federal budget deficit make greater use of
incentive-type approaches to environmental management an attractive option, in some cases.
While existing regulatory systems have made measurable reductions in common air and
water pollutants, most observers agree that they have been less successful against complex
problems caused by toxics and by transformed or transported pollutants. As supplements to
established regulatory systems, market-based options often offer cost saving potentials, enhanced
flexibility, and increased effectiveness. Options include trading of permitted discharges or other
types of resource constraints or over control credits among sources; pollution taxes, fees, and
charges; deposits and refunds; and liability assignment and information disclosure. Particularly
in situations where total pollution loadings or other resource management objectives rather than
ambient health standards are the issue, greater consideration of regulatory financial burdens may
be warranted. More importantly, many environmental problems are too intertwined with
everyday economic activities to be managed effectively through highly centralized regulatory
systems.
Proposals by the Clinton Administration for market-based environmental protection build
on the earlier efforts of Congress and the Bush Administration. The 103rd Congress is
considering market-based approaches in reauthorization for the Clean Water Act. Some in
Congress also propose market-type mechanisms for dealing with the potential threats of global
warming, for encouraging the recycling of solid waste, and for improving management of some
natural resources.
As attractive as these mechanisms may be in concept, their implementation occurs within
a well established regulatory context involving all three levels of government, international treaty
obligations, agency capabilities, and the private sector. It is the implementation concerns that
will largely shape the debate in Congress and help determine which innovations ultimately
become public policy. For example, the political consensus for taxing pollution rests more on
raising
revenue than on any attempt to charge for the external costs of pollution. Similarly, emission
reduction credit or allowance trading systems may offer politically attractive ways to share the
financial burdens of policy changes while also reducing compliance costs.
View Page Image


CONTRIBUTORS
Coordination and Integration
John L. Moore
John E. Blodgett
Air Quality
Larry B. Parker
Susan L. Mayer
David E. Gushee
Water Quality and Resources
Claudia Copeland
John E. Blodgett
Solid and Hazardous Waste
Susan L. Mayer
James E. McCarthy
View Page Image


CONTENTS
INTRODUCTION AND FINDINGS...........................................1
AN EMERGING DOUBLE BIND IN ENVIRONMENTAL MANAGEMENT......1
BEGINNINGS OF A CHANGE IN ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION.........1
IMPLEMENTATION AS THE PRIMARY CONCERN IN
REGULATORY INNOVATION.....................................2
THE OUTLOOK.......................................................2
REPORT CONTENTS AND FOCUS......................................3
FINDINGS ...........................................................3
Growing Interest and Experience......................................3
Options ..........................................................4
Potentials Versus the Pragmatic.......................................5
Cases in Point.....................................................5
Concerns and Limitations...........................................7
THE CONTEXT FOR MARKET-BASED APPROACHES..........................9
THE CURRENT SYSTEM: ITS STRENGTHS AND WEAKNESSES...........10
Strengths .......................................................10
Weaknesses .....................................................11
PRESSURES FOR GREATER USE OF INCENTIVES.......................11
Cost, Finance, and Management Effectiveness..........................12
...............................................................14
Indirect Mechanisms for Complex Environmental Problems...............15
International Obligations...........................................16
CURRENT AND PROPOSED APPROACHES.............................17
Current Examples.................................................17
Proposals for Change..............................................22
ADVANTAGES: POTENTIAL COST SAVINGS AND INNOVATION.........23
Studies of Cost Saving Potentials....................................27
A Stimulus for Innovation..........................................28
CHALLENGES TO IMPLEMENTATION.................................29
Uncertainty in Meeting Environmental Goals...........................30
Third Party Effects and Local Environmental Compliance.................30
Moral Opposition to Local Changes in Pollution ........................30
Measurement and Monitoring.......................................31
Complexity Of Nonconventional Pollutants............................31
Institutional Capability and Authority.................................31
Market Imperfections..............................................32
Regional Definitions and Boundaries.................................32
Compliance Versus Abatement Costs.................................32
Cross-Media Effects...............................................32
INSTITUTIONAL CONSIDERATIONS IN IMPLEMENTATION..................33
THE ROLE FOR MARKET APPROACHES IN A REGULATORY CONTEXT...33
TAXING POLLUTION................................................34
The General Case.................................................34
Implementing Pollution Taxes.......................................35
Other Ways of Using Taxes.........................................36
View Page Image


ii
TRADING OF POLLUTION REDUCTION OR OTHER RESOURCE
MANAGEMENT CONSTRAINTS..................................37
The General Case.................................................37
Implementing Tradeable Pollution or Other Compliance Requirements ......38
Ways of Using Tradeable Permits or Other Over
Performance on Standards.....................................40
DEPOSIT/REFUND ...................................................43
The General Case.................................................43
Implementing Deposit Refund Systems................................43
Ways of Using Deposit-Refund......................................45
OTHER MARKET STRENGTHENING ACTIONS..........................46
Information .....................................................46
Liability Assignment..............................................47
Best Management Practices.........................................48
CURRENT U.S. APPROACHES.............................................49
ACHIEVING REGIONAL/LOCAL REGULATORY EFFICIENCY.............49
Emissions Trading Program.........................................49
Direct Discharge Permit Trading.....................................53
Point-Nonpoint Sources Trading.....................................54
MEETING NATIONAL POLLUTION REDUCTION OR PHASE-OUT
REQUIREMENTS THROUGH TRADING............................59
Lead Trading....................................................59
Sulfur Dioxide Allowance Trading...................................61
INTERNALIZING SOCIAL COSTS THROUGH
NONREGULATORY MEANS......................................66
CFC Tax........................................................66
Permit Fees.....................................................68
Input Fees.......................................................70
Wetlands Mitigation Banking.......................................75
Information Requirements..........................................76
Liability Assignment..............................................78
Deposit-Refund for Managing Solid and Hazardous Waste................79
PROPOSALS FOR NEW APPROACHES......................................81
ACHIEVING REGIONAL/LOCAL REGULATORY EFFICIENCY.............81
Marketable Permit Programs In The Los Angeles Area...................81
MEETING POLLUTION REDUCTION OR PHASE-OUT
REQUIREMENTS THROUGH TRADING............................84
Tradeable Permits For Carbon Dioxide Control.........................84
Recycling Credits in the Solid Waste Area.............................87
INTERNALIZING SOCIAL COSTS THROUGH NONREGULATORY
MEANS ........................................................90
Carbon Taxes....................................................90
Effluent Fees....................................................93
Input Fees - Fertilizer, Pesticide and Animal Feed Tax ...................96
User Taxes - Water Use Tax........................................98
Wetlands Mitigation Banking.......................................99
Assurance Bonding To Reduce Agricultural Nonpoint Source Pollution.....101
Investment Tax Credits for Recycling................................103
View Page Image


iii
Other Tax Credits for Recycling....................................105
Virgin Materials Tax.............................................106
Unit Pricing....................................................107
Deposit/Refund for Batteries and Other Hazardous Substances ............109
TABLES
Table 1.Current Market-Type Mechanisms in Operation.........................19
Table 2.Proposals for Market-Based Environmental Protection....................25
Table 3.Summary of Emissions Trading Activity...............................52
Table 4.Water Pollution Permit Trading (Fox River, Wisconsin)..................56
Table 5.Water Pollution Rights Trading (Dillion Reservoir, Colorado)..............57
Table 6.EPA Lead Trading and Banking.....................................60
Table 7.Implementation Costs by Cost Category...............................62
Table 8.Transactions in Sulfur Dioxide Allowances............................64
Table 9.Relative Comparison of Five Basic Options for Controlling
N Fertilizer Use..................................................73
View Page Image


MARKET-BASED ENVIRONMENTAL MANAGEMENT:
ISSUES IN IMPLEMENTATION
INTRODUCTION AND FINDINGS
AN EMERGING DOUBLE BIND IN ENVIRONMENTAL MANAGEMENT
Increasingly, efforts to protect integral features of the natural environment that are essential
to human well being face a double challenge.
First, the magnitude of some conventional and emerging threats to environmental quality
is growing, despite solid progress in controlling some causes. This is particularly the concern
on a global scale in terms of atmospheric changes and loss of biological diversity.
Second, easily-implemented uniform control methods using feasible technologies or other
direct regulatory approaches are already in place for many pollution and resource management
problems in the United States. Additional progress with so-called command and control policies
can be expensive and disruptive, and thus counter productive to overall economic well being.
This type of dilemma is common where environmental deterioration results from diffuse and
complex causes inherent in technically-advanced high-consumption industrial societies such as
the U.S. Solutions to these types of environmental problems are complicated by the diffuse
benefits which obscures the net gains of additional controls that have concentrated and highly
visible costs.
Given this double bind, many policy analysts and academics have for years advocated more
cost-effective and flexible approaches relying on market forces to further some environmental
management objectives. Although market-based theory and practical environmental policy are
still far apart, the incremental approach to environmental policymaking since the late seventies
has resulted in some market-type innovations within traditional regulatory frameworks at all
levels of government. The most prominent examples are the Environmental Protection Agency's
(EPA) air emissions trading program and the recently enacted sulfur dioxide allowance trading
program under the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments.
BEGINNINGS OF A CHANGE IN ENVIRONMENTAL REGULATION
In enacting environmental legislation, Congress has continually tried to ensure adequate
regulatory and technical controls on individual sources of air, water, and land pollution in order
to protect public health and ecological values. The cost of these controls, while significant in
some cases, had been small enough in the context of the overall economy that through the late
1980s, no viable consensus emerged for specific refinements or shifts in the various laws and
implementing regulations governing environment and natural resources management. This status
quo began to change in 1989 with the push for Clean Air Act Amendments by the Bush
Administration. The need to project low national costs and market-oriented Administration
View Page Image


CRS-2
policy led to the enactment in 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments (CAAA) of the first nationwide
system for trading the location and method for controlling a pollutant (sulfur dioxide).
IMPLEMENTATION AS THE PRIMARY CONCERN IN REGULATORY
INNOVATION
Some argue that the sulfur dioxide trading mechanism marks a new era in environmental
management. Its successful implementation, however, faces significant challenges at the State
level and in the private sector. Other current and proposed market-type innovations face similar
implementation issues.
Since implementation is often the litmus test in assessing the merits of public policy
innovations, this report focuses primarily on the potentials and institutional challenges facing
market-based mechanisms for environmental management within the Federal system.
THE OUTLOOK
The Federal budget situation and the nature of emerging environmental problems are
becoming the factors that focus attention on more active use of incentive approaches for
environmental protection. Expanding the use of fees to finance environmental protection
programs and greater reliance on trading to shift pollution reduction towards lower cost control
points is already done within EPA and State environmental protection programs. Experience to
date suggests a number of directions for the use of these mechanisms including:
•Large direct taxes on pollution, while likely to be effective in the longer term, raise
concerns about U.S. international cost competitiveness, the administrative capability
to implement such techniques, and the political difficulties of applying them in a
targeted way.
A more modest role for environmental taxes is one in which they serve multiple
purposes such as the proposed Btu tax or the recently-passed gasoline tax. The use
of taxes in these circumstances may serve several objectives not necessarily related
to environmental protection, but may possibly modify behavior sufficiently to
produce some reduction in pollution. Such taxes may raise general or dedicated
revenue, send a signal on level of consumption, possibly be used to offset other
revenue sources, or serve as a way of capturing windfall gains when other regulations
drive up prices.
Credit or permit trading is emerging as an acceptable means for easing transitions in
certain situations where strict location of compliance is not a concern. Such systems
can be used to ease the financial burden and opposition to strict local standards for
uniformly distributed environmental problems such as severe ozone nonattainment,
as is the goal in the Los Angeles basin; to lessen economic disruption by allowing
regulated entities to find some other related way to meet a standard or market
constraint as with acid rain control; and to create transitional efficiencies when a
substance or activity is being phased out or substantially reduced in scope, as with
CFCs.
View Page Image


CRS-3
Deposit refund approaches are gaining favor in some States for disposal problems
other than beverage containers. The most common target for this approach is lead
acid batteries, with 10 States operating some type of program. More innovative uses
of this technique, such as management of some toxic substances, remains an untested
proposal.
Information and other market conditioning policies, while indirect and hard to
evaluate, may be one of the more powerful ways to change consumer and business
behavior regarding environmental quality. Anecdotal evidence suggests that the
toxic chemical disclosure requirements of the 1986 Superfund Amendments (Right-to
Know) are leading many corporations to modify practices in order to avoid adverse
publicity even when no legal violations are present.
REPORT CONTENTS AND FOCUS
This report is a revision and update of an earlier CRS report on the same subject.1 This
version looks explicitly at issues of implementation for both existing and proposed market-based
mechanisms. As such, the report is divided into several overlapping sections written to the
interests of various readers. Focus of each major section is:

1)Findings - presents an integration of major points in the report.


2)Context for Market-Based Approaches - presents the range of actual and proposed
mechanisms, their relation to current regulatory systems, and their general strengths
and weaknesses.
3)Institutional Considerations in Implementation - discusses how each of the generic
market-based approaches works, its range of applicability, and the challenges to
implementation within the public sector authorities and capabilities.
4)Current U.S. Approaches - assesses U.S. experience with actual market-based
approaches to-date, focusing on lessons and outcomes relative to expectations.
5)Proposals for New Approaches - assesses some of the major options that are currently
under debate either in Congress or in various policy communities.
FINDINGS
Growing Interest and Experience
With the passage of the trading system for sulfur dioxide, the interest in market-based
refinements among environmental advocacy groups and within Congress has increased for at
least three reasons.
1 U.S. Library of Congress. Congressional Research Service. Using Incentives for
Environmental Protection: An Overview. 89-360 ENR. Washington, 1989.
View Page Image


CRS-4
The country is facing a new round of major pollution control programs -- programs
dealing with possible CO2 reductions, urban ozone reductions, recycling and waste
reduction requirements, nonpoint source water pollution reduction as well as already
enacted efforts to deal with phase out of CFCs and acid rain control. These initiatives
could increase total direct costs of pollution abatement from the historical 2% of the
Gross National Product, where it has remained for nearly 15 years. Facing these
potential cost increases, more efficient control mechanisms begin to look more
attractive. In addition, solutions to some of these problems (such as CO2,
stratospheric ozone depletion, and acid rain), may be more amenable to cost and
efficiency considerations since total regional, national or even international pollution
loadings are involved rather than local ambient concentrations. These circumstances
seem to loosen potential solutions from strict consideration of uniform restraints,
allowing consideration of differences in incremental benefits and costs among
differing circumstances to shape how pollution reduction is accomplished, while still
protecting human health.
Existing regulatory approaches appear inadequate or simply inappropriate for
managing some of the diffuse and more complex pollution problems that are
increasingly apparent -- from toxics and pesticides to global concerns about
stratospheric ozone depletion and climate change. By levying charges or taxes on
pollution, polluting activities or products, or by providing other market incentives,
one may be able to augment existing regulatory and enforcement mechanisms
without resorting to more burdensome and costly methods.
Because of the Federal budget deficit, it is difficult for Congress to authorize and
appropriate monies for new programs to address emerging environmental problems.
Some market-based approaches serve both as potential revenue sources as well as
incentives to modify polluting activities.
Options
Incentive or market-based options give the regulated community a financial reason to
reduce pollution or change other behavior, usually without directives as how such changes
should be made. Although proposals vary, most proponents see incentive approaches as
supplemental to or refining existing environmental regulatory structures rather than replacing
them. Major options include:
Taxes or charges - levied on either polluting outputs, polluting inputs, or polluting
products at a sufficiently high level to make it financially desirable to reduce or even
eliminate pollution;
Fees - levied on pollution discharge permits or other activities and intended generally
to finance regulatory programs;
Tradeable Discharge Permits or Pollution Allowances - various arrangements where
permits or allowances for a fixed amount of pollution can be shifted among pollution
sources through the buying and selling of pollution allowances that concentrate
abatement at the points of lowest cost;
View Page Image


CRS-5
Tradeable Credits - where businesses which over perform in meeting an industry-
wide constraint or objective (removing lead from gasoline, increasing recycled paper
content in newsprint, etc.) are allowed to sell the excess produced to businesses who
cannot meet the objective efficiently thereby achieving gains from trade and lower
compliance costs;
Other - including deposits and refunds; the explicit provision of information; the
assignment of liability; the levying of noncompliance fines or taxes; guidelines;
zoning; cross compliance; and subsidies and tax concessions.
Potentials Versus the Pragmatic
Case studies of potential savings from possible incentive-based systems, usually tradeable
discharge permits, often generate estimates in the tens of billions of dollars. Such results are
usually predicated on unconstrained shifting of pollution reduction requirements to the lowest
incremental-cost points of abatement. As such, these studies ignore existing regulations based
on broader policy concerns and the fact that industries have already spent considerable amounts
on abatement. Estimates of savings from EPA's air emissions trading program suggest industry
savings of several billions of dollars since the beginning of the program in the mid-seventies.
The EPA estimates that the SO2 allowance trading may save $0.7 to $1.0 billion per year over
the course of the program depending on State public utility regulation and the participation of2
utilities.
Besides direct cost saving potentials, there are at least two more subtle, but equally
important considerations. First, proponents argue that incentive-based systems provide financial
motivation for long run innovations that may go beyond traditional regulatory approaches in
solving environmental problems. Second, even if incentive systems do not produce greater
reductions in pollution or improvements in resource management than traditional approaches,
they offer the advantage of flexibility in timing the decisions and methods for meeting
environmental goals, not an insignificant factor in managing private sector activities.
Cases in Point
The EPA's air emissions and SO2 allowance trading program are the most prominent
examples of market-based mechanisms, but several other programs or plans use incentive-type
approaches.
For the SO2 allowance trading program under the acid rain control provisions of the
1990 CAAA, it is too soon to tell whether initial expectations on cost savings will be
realized. Phase I which begins in 1995 requires an intermediate level of reduction
in emissions which many utilities may be able to meet through internal changes. The
exchange of allowances in a market context seems more likely for phase II
allowances which cover emissions of SO2 after the year 2000 and require more
stringent reductions from more sources. Full realization of the potentials of the
2 Carlin, Alan. The United States Experience with Economic Incentives to Control
Environmental Pollution. United States Environmental Protection Agency. 230-R-92-001 July

1992. p. 5-7.


View Page Image


CRS-6
program will depend, in part, on State public utility commissions' policies, support
from State legislatures, and judicial interpretation of State laws.
The 1990 CAAA also contain several provisions that will be implemented in later
years such as fees of $5,000 per ton of excess emissions of volatile organic
compounds; an oxygenated gasoline credit program; and a low emission vehicle
credit program.
For air emissions trading under various EPA mechanisms (netting, bubbling, offsets,
and banking) the results have been mixed, due in part to uncertainties and the
reluctance by regulators and industry to apply these techniques. The most active
"markets" are in Southern California, where stringent pollution limitations on new
industry had been in force prior to the 1990 CAAA and there had been strong
industrial growth. Much of this activity, however, had been credits generated from
plant closings (shut down credits). With the passage of the 1990 Clean Air Act
Amendments, trading activity in Southern California and other areas may be
facilitated by the Act's comprehensive permit program and increasing sanctions for
noncompliance by industry.
Lead phase-down in gasoline was implemented by EPA using a lead rights trading
program among refiners who had differing technical capabilities to remove lead. The
program was generally viewed as successful in reducing the overall industry costs of
complying with stricter lead standards. Some argue that lower costs for marginal
suppliers resulted in lower gasoline prices and thus lower overall industry profits,
while benefitting consumers.
In Colorado, two local governments have established programs for accommodating
future economic growth by allowing water pollution sources with high treatment
costs to "buy" comparable or greater abatement from lower-cost sources, usually
diffuse nonpoint polluters. The program is beginning to be used and is being studied
as a possibility for areas with similar water pollution problems.
Wisconsin has established a statewide discharge permit trading program whose sole
application to date is on the Fox River in order to help achieve regional water quality
standards that had not been met even after dischargers had installed required
pollution control equipment. It appears that limitations on what constitutes tradeable
rights, lengthy approval processes, and other restrictions are the reasons that there has
been virtually no trading within this program.
North Carolina has set an overall limit on nitrogen and phosphorus effluent for one
basin with charges for pollution sources to meet short term goals. In the long-term,
lower discharge limits will probably be imposed through control of nonpoint sources.
Dischargers can offset their effluents with credits issued by a program that controls
agricultural runoff with the most effective management practices.
Most States as well as the Federal government use various forms of permit fees or
taxes to help finance regulatory programs, or in the case of the Federal Superfund to
pay for cleanup of past problems. Such fees are seldom large enough to create an
View Page Image


CRS-7
economic incentive for abatement, though some argue that permit fees for air
emissions in some areas may be high enough to have some incentive effect.
Underlying incentive approaches is the role of better information. Both the Federal
government and various States have made disclosure of pollution information an
explicit requirement for certain types of environmental releases. For example, the
1986 Superfund amendments require that manufacturing companies report annually
on releases of specified hazardous chemicals. New Jersey and California also have
enacted strict disclosure requirements for hazardous substances.
Concerns and Limitations
While incentive-based approaches may be appealing as a refinement to current regulatory
systems, their application in specific situations raises important concerns:
Total pollution control costs could be greater for industry in some cases than
traditional command and control systems, even though abatement expenditures may
be reduced through incentive approaches. This is especially the case where pollution
taxes or auctions of pollution permits would be involved. In this case, industry must
both either pay for all of its pollution or pay for partial cleanup and permits and/or
taxes on the rest. On the other hand, where tradeable permits are grandfathered as
they were with the SO2 allowance trading program, questions of equitable allocations
based on differences in past control have to be addressed. To a large extent, the
working out of an allocation of permits to existing and new sources may involve
complexities and politics as challenging as some aspects of command and control
systems.
Government revenue from an incentive approach (say from pollution taxes or
auctioned permits) would not be recycled to polluters under most proposals. For
example, earlier proposals for a Btu tax (partly justified on environmental and energy
security grounds) would have gone for deficit reduction, as does the increase in the
gasoline tax that was part of the final budget package. There are also a number of
proposals for substantial tax increases on various pollution sources or other problems
such as auto-related congestion with some of the revenue going to reduce income
taxes. However, some advocate earmarking revenues for environmental programs
or to subsidize abatement for vulnerable industry segments. This approach seems to
be popular in Europe.
Incentive systems -- because they allow greater latitude in how and where reductions
occur -- may increase the need for detailed monitoring and enforcement, either at
government or industry (ultimately consumer) expense.
Complexity of both sources and pollutants in the toxics and hazardous waste area
probably confines incentive approaches to areas such as long-run technical change,
recycling, and restraint on quantity used. For example, deposit and refund systems
for some types of toxics have appeal. Information disclosure along with shifting of
the burden of proof may be an effective strategy for motivating non-regulatory
compliance. Taxing polluting inputs may also provide incentives for development
View Page Image


CRS-8
of safer new products or substitution towards less harmful alternatives, as well as
raising product price which reduces the amount demanded.
In situations where environmental deterioration is severe, the relative advantages of
incentive approaches may be small. In these circumstances, every feasible means of
technical control may be needed to achieve environmental standards, if major
lifestyle changes are to be avoided.
To use market-based approaches assumes that markets will not have major
imperfections. Too few buyers and sellers, hoarding, lack of adequate information,
and uncertainty about security of investments in overcontrol are all concerns that
surround trading proposals.
Other potential problems include conflicting objectives between governmental bodies
(e.g., environmental program officials' goals to reduce emissions versus State public
utility commissions' goals on service reliability and cost); and geographic inequities
where different jurisdictions might impose different approaches with different costs;
and potential interstate conflict.
In some cases, there may be an inherent conflict between equitable protection of
individual health and the goal of greater latitude in reducing pollutants.
View Page Image


CRS-9
THE CONTEXT FOR MARKET-BASED APPROACHES
As noted in the introduction, the growing emphasis on market-based approaches seems to
be driven by three trends:
Rising costs from traditional regulatory approaches;
The growing complexity of diffuse sources of environmental deterioration including
nonsustainable pressures on many renewable resources; and
The perceived urgency to reduce the Federal deficit, thus increasing the attractiveness3
of environmental taxes and fees as a revenue source.
Whether these forces will accelerate changes in Federal environmental protection and
resource management policy is unclear, but the thrust of the Administration's early proposals is
toward market-based techniques. In many cases, market-based mechanisms can potentially ease
the transition to more sustainable but controversial environmental and resource management
standards.
In any assessment of current market-based approaches or proposals for change, the policy
and regulatory setting within which techniques are or may be implemented is the necessary
starting point. This section develops that context as background for later discussions of specific
market-based mechanisms. The section covers:
The current regulatory system and its perceived strengths and weaknesses;
The pressures for change;
Current examples of market-based approaches and proposals for new approaches;
The advantages of greater reliance on market-based options;
The concerns about market-based approaches.
3 Some even advocate using pollution taxes as a revenue source to shift tax burdens away
from the income tax while also creating incentives to reduce pollution. See for example: 1)
Oates, Wallace E. Taxing Pollution: An Idea Whose Time has Come? Resources. Spring

1988. Resources For the Future. Washington, D.C. pp 5-7; and 2) Repetto, Robert, et. al.


Green Fees: How a Tax Shift Can Work for the Environment and the Economy. World
Resources Institute. Washington, D.C. November, 1992.
View Page Image


CRS-10
THE CURRENT SYSTEM: ITS STRENGTHS AND WEAKNESSES
Today Federal, State, and local efforts to control environmental deterioration involve a
complex mix of requirements that, taken together, are frequently termed a "command-and-
control" approach. Typical components of this regulatory structure that was developed mostly
in the 1970s include (1) health- or ecology-based standards that are not supposed to be violated,
(2) technology-based or performance-based standards for discharges to the environment, and (3)
permit approval and enforcement procedures for facilities. Liability assignment and fines can
also be important features.
For example, the Clean Water Act establishes technology-based standards for discharges
to water, provides for water quality standards to ensure that remaining discharges adequately
protect water uses, and provides for permits and enforcement. The Clean Air Act establishes
technology-based or performance-based standards for emissions from new sources, establishes
Federal ambient air quality standards which States must develop plans to meet, and creates
elaborate permitting processes that can result in differential requirements depending on whether
the source is new or old and whether it is located (or would be built) in an area complying with
or violating air quality standards. Various provisions of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments,
discussed at several points later in this report, modify the command and control nature of the
Clean Air Act by adding new or expanded market-based policies. The acid rain control title
which authorizes the establishment of a trading system for new limitations on sulfur dioxide
emissions, is the most comprehensive attempt to-date at a market-based solution to a national
environmental problem. In contrast, the Air Toxics title of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments
is probably one of the most "command and control" provisions in environmental law calling for
technology standards on almost 200 different toxic chemicals.
For toxic materials, there are some regulatory variations: for hazardous wastes, the Solid
Waste Disposal Act creates a manifest system for tracking wastes from cradle to an approved
grave; for toxic substances generally, the Toxic Substances Control Act establishes procedures
by which EPA can require firms to test chemicals and, depending on the results, EPA can impose
various restrictions on use, handling, disposal, etc.; and for pesticides, the Federal Insecticide,
Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act provides for Federal registration of individual pesticides, with
labels specifying permitted uses and restrictions.
Strengths
The current system of regulations has provided administrators with some assurance that
technically and economically feasible actions are being taken to abate specific pollutants, and
provides a basis for enforcement in cases of noncompliance. Regulation in each of the media
(air, water, and land disposal) attempts to assure that a variety of standards will be met. In some
cases (i.e. water and new stationary air pollution sources), generally uniform technology is
required on a national basis. In other cases (i.e., existing plants for air pollution sources), State
or local requirements must lead to compliance with national environmental quality standards set
by the Federal government.
This mix of technology requirements, performance standards, and ambient standards
provides regulators with a reasonable degree of predictability in how much pollution levels will
be reduced. The regulatory system has also generally protected the competitive positions of
competing facilities by requiring uniform abatement technology across the country for new
View Page Image


CRS-11
facilities (in air), or by industrial class regardless of facility age (in water); for existing plants
emitting air pollution, requirements are related to imperatives imposed by ambient conditions.
Placing strictest controls on new plants has been based on the assumption that it is cheaper
for new sources to incorporate pollution control and that economic growth will result in the
eventual replacement of older, dirtier facilities. Slower growth and structural change in
manufacturing and electric power sectors since the mid-seventies has tended to work against
these initial assumptions. This approach has also increased the incentive to keep old facilities
in operation longer, further weakening the intended environmental benefits of new source
controls.
Current regulatory policies, however, have scored notable successes. Water bodies have
much less organic pollution compared to thirty years ago. Urban air quality in terms of lead,4
sulfur dioxide, and particulate matter is much improved today over the late sixties.
Weaknesses
In spite of notable progress on some fronts, the system enacted during the seventies has
been unable to achieve several mandatory standards and deadlines established in the authorizing
legislation. Nonattainment of ozone and carbon monoxide ambient air quality standards in
dozens of urban areas is a good example and led to substantial new requirements in the Clean Air
Act Amendments of 1990. Similarly, many water bodies still do not approach their mandated
quality objectives. Proponents of change argue that in such cases ambient standards and
deadlines should be tailored to differences in regional conditions. Regardless of the merits of
that argument, critics contend that more flexible market-based approaches could help achieve
statutory goals in a more timely and less costly way.
There are also many emerging problems where traditional command and control
approaches may not be practical at an acceptable cost. Examples include nonpoint source
pollution of surface and ground water; solid waste disposal; and pesticide and toxics buildup in
land, water, and air. Management of some combustion byproducts and other industrial
chemicals affecting global climate change may be the ultimate environmental challenge for
which treatment technologies would be infeasible regardless of the scale of investment and
deployment. A system based on demand restraint (such as taxes) or quantity restraints (credits)
may be more effective and practical for many current environmental management problems than
extending detailed command and control systems.
PRESSURES FOR GREATER USE OF INCENTIVES
Legislators, regulators, industry, and environmental interest groups until the last few years
provided little support for market-based systems as an acceptable option for dealing with the
4 For trend data and references see: Environmental Quality: The Twenty-third Annual
Report of the Council on Environmental Quality. Part II: Environmental Data Trends.
January, 1993. For more specific data see: National Air Quality and Emission Trends Report,

1992. EPA-454/R-93-031. U.S. EPA Office of Air Quality Planning and Standards. October,


1993.


View Page Image


CRS-12
Nation's environmental management problems. In spite of major criticisms, the various interests
involved with environmental protection largely supported the current regulatory system. For
conventional pollutants, at least, it had done an acceptable job of meeting the concerns of equity,
administrative manageability, public sector cost, and enforceability.
Whether the nineties see a dramatic increase in the use of market-based approaches is a
matter of speculation. There are, however, growing forces that may make some types of market-
based techniques more attractive in the context of broader international, national, state, and local
policy needs. Interrelated policy needs that seem to be promoting a convergence of interests
around greater use of market-based alternatives include:
Cost, finance, and management effectiveness; i.e. the need to deal with growing
control costs, fiscal pressures, and overuse of some resources and environmental
infrastructure;
Indirect mechanisms for complex environmental problems ; i.e.; the need to
find some common ground between strong competing interests in dealing with the
intractability of many environmental problems. (Progress on many environmental
and natural resource problems will require fundamental, equitable, and long term
system and technical changes which may only be possible through indirect changes
in the incentives facing businesses and consumers); and
International obligations; i.e. the prominent role the U.S. plays as both an example
of solutions and as a significant contributor to some global environmental threats
placing the U.S. in potentially difficult positions in international treaty and political
negotiations.
All three needs point in the direction of greater use of market-based policies because such
policies tend to be less intrusive economically than reliance on direct regulation.
Cost, Finance, and Management Effectiveness
Given the double bind facing environmental management - the growing complexity of
many environmental problems and rising control costs - the cost-effectiveness with which
programs can be implemented will help determine how much "environmental protection" can be
had for a given level of public and private expenditures. Also, tying environmental management
and protection costs more explicitly to the beneficiaries using environmental resources can both
serve to cover public sector management costs and act as a signal to users to economize on use.
Cost
While improving environmental quality produces both monetary benefits -such as reduced
corrosion of materials - and nonmonetary benefits - such as healthier ecosystems, the only
comprehensive economic accounting of the effects of environmental protection efforts is the
measurement of control expenditures as part of GNP. The Environmental Protection Agency
estimates that in 1990 the Nation spent just over 2% of its GNP on all forms of environmental
View Page Image


CRS-13
protection.5 There is no corresponding national measure of the value of benefits produced from
such expenditures, since many are nonmonetary, extremely difficult to quantify, or masked in
other areas of GNP accounting. Thus the fraction and rate of growth of "nonproductive"
environmental protection expenditures becomes a source of concern to those focusing on the
costs of production and distribution. The EPA projects that these costs could rise close to 3%
of GNP by the year 2000.
Expenditures on environmental protection ultimately affect product prices, wage rates, and
returns on capital. Costs of products and services have gone up as a result of pollution abatement
requirements, and environmental control costs have also contributed to decisions to close
marginal plants, especially during business slumps.6
Direct increases in the cost of doing business are not the only concern, however. By
increasing private sector uncertainty and delay, some regulatory approaches may also contribute
to slower economic growth. It has been argued that regulatory requirements for multiple permits
and the additional delays caused by judicial appeals may slow the introduction of new7
technologies and reduce flexibility to adapt to changing business conditions.
Thus, major extensions of the existing environmental regulatory approach may raise
increasing objections because of the perception of unnecessary costs it may impose. The
challenge is its practicality for managing the environmental quality needs of a technically8
complex and growing economy and population.
Finance
Beyond the question of escalating control costs under traditional regulatory approaches,
persistent Federal and State budget concerns elevate the environmental area as a revenue source.9
5Environmental Protection Agency. Environmental Investments: The Cost of a Clean
Environment, Report of the Administrator of the EPA to Congress of the U.S. [EPA-230-11-90-

083] (Washington, D.C.: 1990), Tables 8-18.


6 For a comprehensive discussion of the potential economic effects of various Federal
environmental regulations, see: Rusin, Michael et. al. Managing the Environment: A Review
of Present Programs and Their Goals and Methods. Discussion Paper #057. American
Petroleum Institute. Washington, D.C. February 1989.
7Denison, Edward F. Explanations of Declining Productivity Growth. Survey of Current
Business. V. 59. August, 1979. p. 10.
8 For a discussion of the tension between environmental and economic policy objectives, see:
Blodgett, John E. U.S. Library of Congress. Congressional Research Service. Economic and
Environmental Policymaking: Two-Stepping to a Waltz. Report No. 93-264ENR.
Washington, D.C., 1993.
9 Oates, Wallace E. Taxing Pollution: An Idea Whose Time has Come. Loc. Cit. and
Repetto, Robert et. al. Green Fees: How a Tax Shift Can Work for the Environment and the
Economy. Loc. Cit.
View Page Image


CRS-14
Two revenue options are possible. One is the fees currently used by States and Federal
agencies to fund environmental programs; i.e., fee for service. The other is the explicit use of
taxes on pollutants or polluting activities. This latter option is discussed in the next chapter. The
concern here is the legal status of fees and taxes in terms of their potential use.10
Fees. Federal and State agencies assess a variety of fees associated with pollution
discharge permits, harmful inputs, or with some waste volumes. Such fees are largely designed
to raise revenue to cover environmental regulation, research, or other related activities such as
restoration. These fees are usually set at levels that do not create incentives for polluters to
modify their operations; in other words, the fees are significantly less than the cost of any actions
the business or consumer can take to avoid paying the assessment.
A 1986 partial survey of States by the Congressional Budget Office found that for air,
water, and hazardous waste permits, only seven States did not use some form of environmental11
fee in their regulatory programs. States use a wide variety of permit-fee structures including:
uniform fees; fees that vary by size of output of the polluting facility; fees that vary by the type
of facility; fees that vary by the type of permit; fees that vary by the volume of pollution
emissions; fees that vary by the toxicity of the discharge or the type of pollutant; and fees that
vary with the destination of discharge.
At the Federal level, certain types of fees may be set by an administrative agency to cover12
regulatory or program costs. The legislative authority for agency fees comes from one of
several sources: 1) specific provisions in an authorizing statute; 2) authorization provided in
appropriations legislation; and 3) fee collection authority derived from the Independent Offices
Appropriation Act of 1951. In the latter case, fees cannot in reality be a tax; e.g., they must be
proportional to value or service obtained from the groups subject to the fees. Also, receipts go
to the general fund unless Congress specifies otherwise in authorizations or appropriations
language. These and other restrictions in the 1951 Act are intended to preserve the exclusive
power of Congress to levy taxes and to oversee and limit agency growth not authorized by
Congress.
Taxes. An alternative to fees is taxation of polluting activities or substances. Using
taxation as opposed to fees allows greater flexibility in selecting bases and rates and in using the
tax to raise large amounts of revenue. Taxes, if high enough, will also potentially affect polluting
behavior.
10 One other fiscal option affecting resource and environmental management is below-cost
pricing policies for some publicly-owned resources. While change in these policies has both
environmental and fiscal implications, this report focuses only on the direct use of market-type
mechanisms rather than long standing public sector policies which use resource pricing to foster
economic development or maintain community stability in rural areas.
11 U.S. Congressional Budget Office. Environmental Charges. August 1987.
12U.S. Congressional Budget Office. The Growth of Federal User Charges. Washington,
D.C. August, 1993.
View Page Image


CRS-15
There are two other important contrasts between environmental taxes and program fees.
First, the only restrictions on environmentally oriented taxes are constitutional considerations of
due process and equal protection. However, the constitutional requirement that Federal taxes be
uniform throughout the United States may have implications for some types of incentive-based
approaches. Another distinction noted by CBO is the basing of taxes on market values (sales,
income, or assets), whereas fees are based on non market actions such as licenses, permits, and
government services.
Management Effectiveness
In some cases, rates of use of certain renewable natural resources may exceed the long term
carrying capacity of the resource base under current authorities, institutional arrangements, and
behavior of vested interests. In other cases, an environmental objective may be very costly to
reach through across-the-board requirements on all actors.
Under these general circumstances, trading of the location or method of compliance often
allows the private sector to respond more quickly at less cost to the economy as a whole. The
mechanism involves public intervention to establish a total constraint on total pollution, resource
use, or on other characteristics. Regulated entities are then allowed to trade the location and
method of compliance to their own economic advantage.
Indirect Mechanisms for Complex Environmental Problems
Increasingly, the environmental degradation affecting air, water, and land are the result of
pervasive activities for which traditional "end of the pipe" technologies or command and control
regulations may be neither affordable nor practical. Toxic substances, CO2, pesticides, and
nonpoint source water pollution are examples typically cited. These types of degradation are
often linked with growing material standards of living; growing population; and the technology
of everyday agricultural, industrial, transportation, and consumer products and processes.
Although conventional pollutants are also associated with economic and population growth, their
emissions levels can still be further reduced with reasonably available technologies.
The seeming intractability of dealing with toxics and pesticide pollution problems arises
from the sheer number of substances, their volumes and diffusion, and the resources and time
demands for evaluating the safety of each one.13 Evaluation difficulties arise for several reasons:
these substances may be biologically active at extremely low concentrations; some of them may
magnify in the food chain; they may cause diverse, subtle, and delayed effects in the form of
cancer or neurological and gene damage; and they may have the potential for accumulation,
cycling in the food chain, and transformation to more harmful substances in the environment.
Congress has passed several major acts directed at toxic substances and pesticides.
Requirements of these acts include testing and evaluation of relative risks and benefits,
registration, application requirements, and substance tracking. Specific requirements for toxics
13 In contrast to the limited number of conventional pollutants, more than 60,000 chemical
products and 1,200 active pesticide ingredients used in over 35,000 formulations give rise to
potential human and ecological hazards.
View Page Image


CRS-16
include regulations on discharge and disposal methods, liability assignment, and fee-supported
cleanup and insurance funds.
Given the complexity and consequences of toxic and other hazardous substances, few
dispute the need for strengthening and improving regulatory approaches. In spite of progress in
dealing with toxics and pesticides, however, the sheer volume and complexity of these
substances present EPA with an enormous information and management burden, and are
considered possible causes in the major delays in meeting various statutory goals. In total, the
EPA estimates that there are over 650,000 generators of hazardous wastes, a figure which does
not include the pesticides used on over two million farms. Annual disposal of toxic wastes in all
media may be as much as one billion tons.14
The fact that so many businesses and individuals use and dispose of hazardous and toxic
substances suggests that future progress in dealing with this problem may require greater use of
flexible and decentralized approaches. In this context, proponents argue that supplemental
market-oriented approaches, such as taxes or deposits and refunds, may be worth considering.
These would provide incentives to reduce the volumes of hazardous products, to encourage
recycling and proper disposal, or ultimately to design less harmful products.
Nonpoint source contamination of surface and groundwater presents similar problems.
Diffuse urban and rural sources of organics, sediment, toxic chemicals, pesticides, and other
contaminants contribute an estimated fifty percent of remaining surface water pollution loadings;
and the dispersed land disposal of wastes and use of agrichemicals pose problems of groundwater
contamination as well. Education on best management practices can help reduce these problems,
but the practicality of technical controls is limited and extending strict regulatory approaches
would present enormous enforcement costs, and problems of political acceptability. Often the
polluting activity or substance is a small part of operational cost but yields large financial returns.
Cases in point include nitrogen fertilizers and many pesticides used in agriculture. Liberal
application of these substances may seem wasteful and is ultimately harmful to the environment,
but to use them more precisely seldom makes sense financially to individuals and businesses.
At current prices and with current technology, wiser use, in an environmental sense, may require
too much management, labor, and information. Again in this context, proponents of new
directions often propose fees or taxes on these substances to help modify individual business and
consumer behavior.
Perhaps the most complex environmental challenge is the role combustion byproducts and
other man-made substances may be playing in global climate modification. Although this topic
is fraught with major uncertainties, proponents of accelerating government actions typically call
for a range of incentive-oriented approaches, including both taxes and trading of the location of
controls
International Obligations
The United States along with other members of the international community have created
or are creating treaty mechanisms to begin efforts to cope with perceived global environmental
14 Office of Technology Assessment. From Pollution to Prevention: A Progress Report
on Waste Reduction. Washington, D.C. U.S. Government Printing Office. 1987. p. 19
View Page Image


CRS-17
threats. These threats to long term environmental quality include loss of species diversity and
habitat, loss of forested areas, atmospheric changes (greenhouse gas buildup and stratospheric
ozone depletion), and growing depletion of ocean and terrestrial wildlife resources shared among
nations.
Part of this growing international imperative is an increasing emphasis on the concept of
"sustainable development." Though ill-defined, it symbolizes the longer term norms proponents
of change seek in technology, institutions, and economic systems in order to move toward a
complementary relationship between human use of the environment on the one hand and
maintenance of life support systems and biological richness on the other.
Given this international context, the U.S. is in a somewhat unique and difficult diplomatic
position. As a world leader, we have often been on the forefront of environmental treaties to
protect the common world interest, the case in point being stratospheric ozone protection. On
the other hand, we are also a significant contributor to some of the long term negative
environmental trends because of the relative size of our economy and our extensive use of fossil
fuels. Thus our stake in the methods proposed for long term changes is indeed large. For that
reason, market-based options which typically provide flexibility and decentralized response, are
often proposed as a less intrusive way to meet potential obligations to future international
agreements.
CURRENT AND PROPOSED APPROACHES
In the mid-seventies, Federal and State agencies began using some incentive-type
strategies, primarily as mechanisms to support the basic "command-and-control" requirements.
Though limited in scope, these strategies typically involve trading of allowed air emissions
among sources through offsets, netting, or bubble arrangements. Other examples include the
noncompliance penalties in the Clean Air Act. The sulfur dioxide allowance trading system in
the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments builds on this earlier experience.
Legislative proposals in the current and recent Congresses for incentive or market-based
policy tools are outgrowths of these earlier refinements to environmental regulations. Proposals,
in reauthorization efforts for the Clean Water Act and the Resource Conservation and Recovery
Act, for pollution charges or tradeable recycled materials credits are examples. A number of bills
directed at committing the United States to actions to slow emissions of greenhouse gases have
included market-based approaches such as a carbon tax or various forms of carbon dioxide
emissions trading.
Current Examples
At the Federal level, statutory authorities and regulatory implementation in a few areas now
incorporate market-based approaches. Table 1 based on a recent EPA report summarizes the
View Page Image


CRS-18
variety of mechanisms currently operational or authorized by recent changes in the law.15 EPA
groups current examples under the following headings:
Fees, Charges, and Taxes;
Deposit-Refund Systems;
Trading Systems;
Emissions Averaging;
Others such as information provision and liability assignment.
States and the Federal government rely to varying degrees on permit and other fees as a
revenue source for environmental programs and related activities. While these fees typically
have not been sufficiently large to provide incentives to modify polluting activities, their use
raises the possibilities of future extension to more incentive-oriented environmental charges.
Indeed, the Clean Air Act Amendments include authorization in cases of future noncompliance
for permit fees that may exceed the incremental cost of abatement. A few examples of fees at
the State level include New York's fee system for hazardous waste disposal, Iowa's nonpoint
source fee on pesticides, fees under the State and Federal Superfunds, and State oil spill funds.
Other innovations at the State/local level include making the incremental cost of environmental
services more explicit to the user. Charging on a per-bag basis for municipal trash collection is
one example. Volume or time-differentiated water or sewer charges are another.
Refundable deposits for beverage containers and for lead acid batteries are now being used
in several States to reduce litter and disposal problems. Deposit-refund systems have also been
proposed for certain toxic and hazardous substances management.
Trading systems have become a feature of environmental policy at all levels of government.
For example, the 1990 Amendments to the Clean Air Act addressed the
15 Carlin, Alan. The United States Experience with Economic Incentives to Control
Environmental Pollution. United States Environmental Protection Agency. 230-R-92-OO1.
Washington, D.C. July, 1992.
View Page Image


CRS-19
TABLE 1. CURRENT MARKET-TYPE MECHANISMS IN OPERATION
FEES, CHARGES AND TAXES
Permit Fees
National Pollution Discharge Elimination System -- State permit system for water pollution discharges under
the 1972 Federal Water Pollution Control Act. Some States differentiate fees based on volume and toxicity
of effluent.
Publicly-Owned Sewage Treatment Plant User fees -- Charges on industrial facilities and households
discharging into their systems. Fees may have some effect on large industrial dischargers.
Municipal Solid Waste Disposal Charges -- At least 2,000 jurisdictions base charges on volume. In addition,
most private collectors impose volume-based charges.
Air Emission Fees --
--State permit fees for administrative costs with California highest in the Nation at $300-$600 per ton of
pollutant. Even these rates are below incremental control costs.
--Federal Nonattainment Area Fees under the Clean Air Act Amendments. Some provisions allow
recovery of administrative costs over a 20 year period. Failure to achieve reduction of excess emissions
in extreme ozone nonattainment areas will subject stationary sources to a $5,000 per ton (adjusted for
inflation) annual fee for each ton of volatile organic compound emitted. Fees in the form of highway
tolls are also allowed to reduce pollution and congestion.
Industrial Solid and Hazardous Waste Charges -- Private waste disposal firms charge based on the
number of containers emptied and content.
Product Charges --
--Fertilizer taxes by States to help pay for programs for environmental protection and research.
--Automobile Tire Taxes -- State and county taxes with revenue marked for used tire recycling and
disposal.
--Motor Oil Taxes -- Rhode Island imposes a fee earmarked for used oil collection costs.
--Superfund Feedstock Taxes on domestic crude oil production, crude oil and petroleum product imports,
and petrochemical feedstocks to finance in part program costs.
--Chlorofluorocarbon taxes under the Budget Reconciliation Act of 1989 to accelerate reduction in the use
of ozone-depleting chemicals.
Wetland Compensation Fees -- Maryland and New Jersey allow payments for unavoidable wetlands loss with
proceeds available for wetland enhancement and restoration.
View Page Image


CRS-20
TABLE I (continued)
DEPOSIT-REFUND SYSTEMS
Beverage Container Deposits in 10 States resulting in sharp reduction in litter.
Battery Deposits required in at least 10 States. A $5 to $10 deposit at point of sale is required and deposits
are refundable if an old battery is returned within a specified period. In addition, retailers increasingly are
using deposits to insure that used batteries are returned in jurisdictions without formal deposit legislation.
Pesticide container deposits required by Maine to promote triple rinsing and return of commercial containers.
TRADING SYSTEMS
Inter-Firm Non-Approval Trading
Acid Rain Allowance Trading under Title IV of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments -- Allowing coal
burning utilities to trade the location and method of SO2 reductions mandated by the law.
Oxygenated Gasoline Credit Program under Title II of the Clean Air Act Amendments -- Requires gasoline
in certain cities to contain 2% oxygen and allows refiners, blenders or importers who produce greater than 2%
oxygenated gasoline to sell credits to refiners who are unable to meet the 2% requirement. Only the
Philadelphia region has established a trading program, and activity has been minimal to date.
Low Emission Vehicle Credit Program under the 1990 CAAA -- Authorizes California to offer marketable
credits to auto manufacturers that sell more low emission vehicles than are required under the pilot test
program for clean-fuel vehicles and alternative fuels.
Chlorofluorocarbon Production Allowance Trading -- In response to the 1988 Montreal Protocol and the 1990
CAAA on phaseout of CFCs, EPA established rules apportioning baseline allowances, providing for gradual
reduction in allowances and permitting the transfer of allowances among firms.
Lead trading as part of the last part of lead phaseout in gasoline -- Refiners that removed greater amounts of
lead than were required could trade credits to those who were above the limit.
Transferable Development Rights -- Whereby local jurisdictions downzone environmentally sensitive areas
and then require areas of higher land use density to purchase development rights from the downzoned area.
Examples include Montgomery and Talbot Counties, Maryland and the Pinelands, New Jersey.
Fireplace and Wood Stove Permit Trading -- To reduce particulate matter and carbon monoxide. This
program to reduce local air pollution in Teluride, Colorado uses a combination of performance standards for
existing stoves, a time-limited $750 rebate for conversion to natural gas, and a ban on fireplaces in new
construction unless the developer bought two permits surrendered by existing users.
View Page Image


CRS-21
TABLE I (continued)
Inter-Firm Approval Trading
Air Emission Rights
Trading of Air Emissions Rights (EPA) -- Bubbles allowing firms to treat multiple emission points as one
source for control purposes.
Offsets (EPA) -- Allowing new plants locating in an area that violates air quality standards to buy reduction
in emissions to insure that air quality does not deteriorate.
Banking (EPA) -- Allows saving or banking of emission reduction credits for later use or sale.
Netting (EPA) -- Allows plant expansion that avoids stricter, new source standards so long as plant wide
emissions do not increase significantly.
Water Effluent Reduction Trading
Wisconsin -- Allowing industrial plants that reduce biological oxygen demand below the standards to trade
the excess reductions to other sources.
Dillon Reservoir, Colorado -- Allowing high cost point sources of nutrients discharge to the reservoir to buy
lower cost reductions from nonpoint sources.
Cherry Creek Reservoir, Colorado -- Allows publicly-owned wastewater treatment plants to earn reduction
credits by purchasing control of nonpoint phosphorous discharges after these sources have made reduction
of 50% on their own.
Tar Pemlico Basin, North Carolina -- The State sets an overall limit on nitrogen and phosphorous effluent with
the possibility of charges for failure by effluent sources to meet short-term goals. In the long-term, lower
discharge limits will probably be imposed through control of nonpoint sources. Dischargers are creating a
fund to pay for nonpoint source control.
Steel Industry Effluent Bubble (EPA) -- Allowing steel plants to treat multiple sources in one treatment
system.
Wetland Mitigation Banking (U.S. Fish and Wildlife Service) -- Involving creation of new wetlands and
mitigation credits available to developers to meet State-imposed mitigation requirements.
EMISSIONS AVERAGING
This is equivalent to emissions trading within a plant or firm and is used to meet Reasonably Available Control
Technology (RACT) standards. Examples include RACT requirements, Heavy Duty Truck Engine Emissions, California
Motor Fuel Characteristics, and Hazardous Air Pollutants Early Reduction Program.
OTHER METHODS
Several other methods using incentives and other market conditioning techniques have been implemented in recent
years. These include traditional inducements to change behavior or operations such as tax concessions or subsidies;
assignment of liability for prescribed categories of damages or negligence; and the provision of information on risks,
product characteristics, or other operational or site data that facilitates or improves business and consumer decision
ma k i n g .
Source: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. The United States Experience with Economic Incentives to Control
Environmental Pollution. 230-R-92-001. July 1992.
View Page Image


CRS-22
acid rain problem by giving new authority to EPA to use a market-based approach for achieving
targeted reductions in sulfur dioxide emissions. The Amendments authorized EPA to establish
a nationwide system for trading the location of sulfur dioxide (SO2) reductions among emission
sources with differing reduction costs. This innovation may have the effect of lowering the long
run compliance costs of electric utilities in meeting legislated targets for reductions in SO2. At
the regulatory level, EPA has since the late seventies allowed various forms of air emission
trading for stationary sources within narrowly prescribed circumstances. EPA also implemented
a credit trading program to ease the transitional costs for refiners in phasing out lead in gasoline
during the 1980s. The goal in all of these cases has been to help reduce the cost to industry of
meeting environmental standards.
State and regional-level innovations have often been within implementation responsibilities
under Federal environmental statutes such as the Clean Air Act. For example, the South Coast
Air Quality Management District in California used a negotiated rule-making process to
introduce emission trading between facilities as a cost-effective way to reduce the costs of
meeting strict health-based ozone standards. In other examples, States have implemented plans
and trading programs, but limited trading has occurred to date. These include two watersheds
in Colorado to reduce future nonpoint source problems and Wisconsin's Fox River waste load
allocation program to attain regional water quality goals. North Carolina also has a similar
mechanism in place for one river system. Locally, communities have applied trading as a way
to reduce pollution from excessive fireplace use in Colorado, for example.
As indicated in the table, other mechanisms include emissions averaging, plants or firms
can average overall emissions to meet a standard; liability assignment in which findings of
damages to third parties carry specified financial compensation; the provision of various types
of information to improve knowledge of risks, both for consumer and business decision making;
and the use of subsidies or tax concessions to induce changes in operation or behavior deemed
to be in the public interest.
Some other types of incentive programs in operation also bear on environmental quality.
For example, at the Federal level, the schedule of fees imposed on continued ocean dumping
after 1991 and the economic-based noncompliance penalties under the Clean Air Act both serve
as incentives to meet environmental standards.
Proposals for Change
While academic economists have long been the major proponents of market-oriented
changes in environmental regulation, these concepts are now actively debated by many in the
policy arena. For example, Table 2 presents some of the types of recent proposals including
those based mainly on two projects sponsored by Senator Wirth and the late Senator Heinz which
View Page Image


CRS-23
have been a focal point for further studies and debate.16 Generic and specific examples of the
various mechanisms in Table 2 are discussed in subsequent sections.
As the table suggests, many of the proposals for greater use of market-based mechanisms
focus on tradeable overcontrol or overperformance on some form of management objective. The
other recurring theme is the more direct use of taxes on polluting activities or products, such as
the Btu tax initially included in the Administration's plan for reducing the Federal budget deficit.
ADVANTAGES: POTENTIAL COST SAVINGS AND INNOVATION
Proponents of decentralized or market-based policies cite the potential cost savings and
efficiency of these alternatives. The general argument is that systems of environmental
regulation which allow flexible responses, or abatement trading among sources with differing
reduction costs, save money. Proponents see such alternatives as both a supplement to traditional
regulatory approaches and as a cost-effective way of attacking emerging problems.
Although proponents talk about market or incentive approaches to environmental
protection, this does not imply markets in the form of daily price quotes and frequent exchanges
of products or property. Rather, proposed approaches would act to increase the flexibility of
meeting environmental or resource management objectives (usually limitations on total pollution
over some broader geographic area) through greater latitude in when, where, and how
adjustments in technology, fuel, materials, or rates of resource use are implemented.
The hoped for objective is less costly management of environmental quality and natural
resources than can be done by trying to extend traditional regulatory methods. In essence, these
types of mechanisms help to focus decision making by making the cost of environmental
management more explicit to both businesses and consumers. This in turn creates reasons to be
innovative to make the cost of compliance as low as possible, thus rationing the absorptive
capacity of the environment similar to the way markets serve to ration any scarce good or service
through the price mechanism.
For the major market-based tools, taxes and tradeable overcontrol of pollution or other
standards, cost savings to society may result for two related reasons. First, flexibility in method,
location, degree of abatement, and contracting arrangements within the regulated community can
lead to less resources expended to meet environmental management objectives. Control is
concentrated at the most cost-effective locations as a result of self-interested trading among the
regulated community, assuming that local environmental standards are met. Second, with both
taxes and tradeable overcontrol, a continuing motivation exists to innovate to avoid the taxes or
create overcontrol that can be sold. If this type of incentive remains a constant and predictable
part of the business or consumer environment, and there are few, if any restraints on how
16 Project 88 -- Round II, Incentives for Action: Designing Market-Based Environmental
Strategies. A Public Policy Study sponsored by Senator Timothy E. Wirth, Colorado and
Senator John Heinz, Pennsylvania. Washington, D.C. May 1991. See also the earlier version
of this report sponsored by the same Senators - Project 88, Harnessing Market Forces to
Protect our Environment: Initiatives for the New President. A Public Policy Study. John F.
Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University. Cambridge, MA. December, 1988.
View Page Image


CRS-24
compliance is achieved, then, proponents argue, longer term cost savings are likely through
innovation and substitution compared to the stereotypical command and control system.
While total cost to society for meeting environmental standards can be less in theory, under
some market-based options total industry compliance costs can be much higher, since regulated
entities must not only pay to use the waste disposal capacity of the environment (through
purchased permits or pollution taxes), but also pay for any abatement they undertake to avoid
taxes or the need to buy overcontrol from somebody else. While expenditures on taxes or
overcontrol are considered transfers within society not affecting the real resource cost of
compliance, they raise the direct compliance cost to industry. Opposition by industry to such
mechanisms, is in part, based on this type of concern.
View Page Image


CRS-25
TABLE 2. PROPOSALS FOR MARKET-BASED ENVIRONMENTAL PROTECTION
ENVIRONMENTAL PROBLEM MARKET-TYPE PROPOSALS
Air Pollution
Major Stationary Urban SourcesComprehensive Tradable Permits
requires baseline inventory
special credit for previous reductions
progressive reduction in permit amounts
fines exceeding market value of permits
Mobile SourcesTaxes and Emissions Charges
taxes on low-mileage cars
charges for automobile use
tax on gasoline
Radon(indoor air pollution)Mandatory Information
require certification of radon "free" status of house to
qualify for FHA financing
Wa t e r
Point SourceWatershed Limitations
tradable permits -- similar to air programs

Nonpoint Source
SurfacePoint-Nonpoint Source Swaps
Point sources buy reductions in nonpoint sources in
order to meet water quality goals (two for one exchange
to assure actual reductions)
directed toward nitrogen and phosphorus loadings
Broaden Conservation Reserve Program
GroundwaterConservation Easements
swap farm debt for use restrictions
PesticidesTaxes on most damaging products
View Page Image


CRS-26
TABLE 2 (continued)
ENVIRONMENTAL PROBLEM MARKET-TYPE PROPOSALS
Municipal Wastes
Recycling Targets and Tradeable Credits
Establish recycling content regulations and allow purchase
or sale of over compliance/under compliance between firms.
Unit Pricing
Charge by volume of residential waste
Retail Disposal Charges
Surcharges on sale of goods to reflect disposal costs
Virgin Materials Charges
Charges on virgin materials to reflect eventual disposal costs
and stimulate use of secondary (recycled) materials
Hazardous Substances
ToxicsDeposit and Refund System on
Containerizable Hazardous Wastes
Greenhouse Effect
New-Major C02 SourcesOffset Policy where New Sources Buy Comparable reductions in CO2
from energy conservation
from plant retirement
from mass transit investments
from reforestation joint ventures
Taxes on Major Sources of Carbon Emissions
Carbon tax
Btu tax
Gasoline tax
Deforestation Mitigation from Conservation Reserve Program
from international forest for debt swaps
View Page Image


CRS-27
Studies of Cost Saving Potentials
Several earlier studies have looked at this theoretical potential for less costly abatement
approaches through market-based approaches, mainly permit trading.17,18,19 In almost all cases,
these estimates are achieved from simulation models in which current regulations and past
abatement expenditures are not considered. As such, these types of studies will overstate what
might actually be saved from the use of permit trading starting from conditions and regulations
as they currently exist. For example, an earlier survey of several region-specific case studies
suggests that the cost of attaining air quality standards might have been reduced in the range of
fifty percent between 1981 and 1990 if least-cost control had been achieved through
unconstrained emissions trading.20 This would have amounted to tens of billions in savings.
Hester and Hahn, on the other hand, suggest that savings from the current air emissions trading
program have been a few billion.21
In looking at theoretical or simulation type studies, the extent to which regulatory
constraints on local environmental quality have been excluded from the analysis must also be
considered when evaluating potential savings from emissions trading; that is, if dirty high-cost
facilities would not be allowed to violate local quality standards even if total regional pollution
could be reduced more cheaply through some form of trade, then theoretical savings will be
diminished. In addition, the regulatory approaches may promote values other than cost-
effectiveness, such as equity and energy policy considerations, among others.
This potential for major cost savings underlying most of the modelling studies is due to the
often large differences in pollution control costs among sources. These potential cost variations
among similar sources are the result of differences in scale, age, technology, cost and ease of
substituting inputs, management practices, and location, among other factors. For example,
studies show that average cost effectiveness across control measures for volatile organic
compounds (VOCs) may range from about $500 per ton for limits on fuel volatility to about
17United States General Accounting Office. A Market Approach to Air Pollution Control
Could Reduce Compliance Costs Without Jeopardizing Clean Air Goals. PAD-82-15.
March, 1982.
18 ICF Resources Incorporated. Economic, Environmental, and Coal Market Impacts of
SO2 Emissions Trading Under Alternative Acid Rain Control Proposals. Prepared for the
U.S. Environmental Protection Agency and the U.S. Department of the Interior by ICF Resources
Inc. March, 1989.
19 Hahn, Robert W. and Hester, Gordon L. Where Did All the Markets Go? An Analysis of
EPA's Emissions Trading Program. Yale Journal on Regulation. Vol. 6, Winter 1989.
pp.109-153
20 Tietenberg, T. Emissions Trading: An Exercise in Reforming Public Policy. Resources
for the Future. Washington, D.C. pp. 42-43.
21 Hahn and Hester. Loc. Cit. p. 63.
View Page Image


CRS-28
$39,000 per ton for using methanol.22 Typical control costs for VOCs are in the range of $1,000
to $7,000 per ton. Other types of pollutants may have less extreme, but none the less significant,
differences in incremental reduction costs. For example, a series of water pollution control
studies suggested potential saving with least-cost approaches of 20 to 70 percent compared to
equal-proportional treatment of pollution sources.23
Even though major cost variations may hold promise for more cost-effective pollution
control, realizing the savings may not always be practical using extensions of the current system.
For example, most large, low cost sources of pollution abatement are already making pollution
reductions under current regulations. Many of the remaining sources with low incremental
reduction costs may be small individual contributors. Such small activities probably cannot bear
the cost of expensive control technology, but could reduce emissions through changes in
management practices or other operational adjustments. Applying market-based approaches to
these types of problems, however, may involve approaches that are not likely to be
administratively practical, such as taxing inputs or complex polluting byproducts. The latter
implies a very high degree of monitoring or self reporting, both of which have drawbacks.
Another consideration is the stringency of control necessary to achieve environmental
standards. In an area with significant violations of environmental standards (e.g., air in Los
Angeles), virtually every significant pollution source of ozone precursors and of carbon
monoxide may require maximum feasible reductions if ambient standards are to be approached.
Under these circumstances, market-based approaches may reduce inefficiencies in timing and
location of controls, facilitating the implementation of strict standards and reducing indirect
costs, but not appreciably affect total costs.24
A Stimulus for Innovation
Incentive-based approaches may promote lower cost abatement where existing sources of
environmental degradation are required to make major changes. However, a more subtle, but
equally relevant point is the stimulus that market signals can provide for long-term innovations
that might change entire pollution generating products and activities. Incentive systems also
offer important flexibility in timing, important to private sector investment decision-making.
While it has not been demonstrated that current regulatory systems inhibit innovation and
technical advance in environmental protection, proponents argue that incentive systems reduce
the risk that such inhibition will occur. For example, most current environmental regulation is
directed to the removal or transformation of pollutants from industrial, municipal, and mobile
sources or to the control of harmful products entering the environment such as pesticides and
toxics. Solutions to environmental management problems consequently tend to focus on "end25
of the pipe" treatment technologies and on disposal practices.
22 Office of Technology Assessment. Urban Ozone and the Clean Air Act: Problems and
Proposals for Change. April 1989. Washington, D.C. pp. 106-108.
23 Tietenberg, T.H. Op. Cit., p. 46.
24 Tietenberg, T.H. Op. Cit., pp. 45-47.
25Although the use of "best available control technology" and new source performance
(continued...)
View Page Image


CRS-29
This is not to say that current regulatory systems do not create pressures for cleaning-up
as well as avoiding polluting activities. Adjustments in internal combustion engine technology
along with installation of catalytic converters is a case in point.
The costs of meeting permit conditions, engaging in possible litigation, or paying fines do
provide indirect incentives to engage in avoidance strategies that may reduce pollution.
However, these types of adjustments to regulatory requirements are often in the form of delay,
uncertainty, transactions costs, shutdowns, and decisions that may later prove to be inadequate
or misguided. Where avoidance of regulatory burdens takes a positive form, it may be through
adjusting production processes, changing product lines or inputs, or taking other pollution
reducing activities.
Proponents of incentive systems argue that cost signals should be more explicitly focused
on the polluting substance or activity if we want to do a better job of long-run environmental
management. They argue that there may be any number of ways of reducing the level of
pollutants ultimately reaching environmental media. Having the incentives and flexibility to be
able to choose how and where to make changes can reduce the need for costly removal
technologies. For example, if the impacts on employment in vulnerable segments of the high-
sulfur coal industry were ignored, an unrestrained incentive-based system would likely lead to
large scale shifting to low sulfur coal. This would be a market-based outcome, since using low-26
sulfur coal is generally a much less expensive option than installing scrubbers. In passing the
acid rain portion of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments, however, Congress chose to design
the sulfur dioxide allowance trading system in way that gives some incentives to use scrubbers
that may give some protection to high sulfur coal miners, while still creating the most potentially
comprehensive market-based approach to date.
CHALLENGES TO IMPLEMENTATION
The preceding alludes to some of the institutional challenges in implementing market-based
systems. General concerns include political acceptability, geographical equity, and practicability.
In particular, affected parties may be very reluctant to accept incentive approaches. There are,
moreover, several specific and interrelated policy concerns that accompany proposals for
incentive-oriented policies.
Specific problems include lack of certainty in attaining environmental goals; third party and
local environmental compliance; measurement and monitoring costs; boundary inequities;
institutional capability and authority; market imperfections; compliance versus abatement costs;
complexity in pollution sources; and cross-media effects.
25(...continued)
standards were supposed to encourage and even "force" new technology.
26 See for example: 1) Streets, David G. and Veselka, Thomas D. Economic Incentives for
the Reduction of Sulfur Dioxide Emissions. Energy Systems and Policy. Vol. 11, pp. 39-59,

1987. 2) Harrington, Winston. Breaking the Deadlock on Acid Rain Control. Resources. Fall,


1988. Resources for the Future. Washington, D.C.


View Page Image


CRS-30
The various incentive approaches discussed in the next chapter are subject in varying
degrees to these specific policy problems. Also, the current command and control system
confronts many of the same concerns.
Uncertainty in Meeting Environmental Goals
Raising the cost of polluting activities or products through charges or taxes can be expected
to lead to reduced pollution levels over some difficult to predict time period. This will happen
so long as the costs of reduction for some businesses or consumers are less than the charges
associated with the polluting activity. However, in a complex economy, it is difficult to predict
accurately how much reduction will occur, how fast it will occur, and what combination of short
and long run alternatives the private sector may use to make reductions.
Thus, if regulators were to add incentive-oriented modifications to current regulatory
systems, the resulting pace of improvement toward environmental goals or standards might or
might not be considered acceptable. Proponents believe that charge adjustments could fine tune
these systems based on initial response. However, frequent changes to adjust the incentive
structure would doubtless lead to criticisms similar to those made of the current system where
numerous changes make private sector response more difficult and inefficient. A further
complication arises if incentive fees also serve to finance the regulatory program. If successful
in reducing the polluting activity, the financing base would be reduced.
Tradeable permits may offer regulators an incentive option with less uncertainty than taxes
or fees. Since permits are for a fixed amount of pollution or other compliance goal, enforcing
compliance with the permit terms should, in total, meet specified standards.
Uncertainty would also affect the private sector's response. If permit conditions and
amounts were not firm or were subject to future change, trading and markets would be retarded.
Similarly, lengthy processes, hearings, intervention points, and possibilities of lawsuits typically
retard or eliminate potentials for cost-saving exchanges.
Third Party Effects and Local Environmental Compliance
Any market-based approach that would result in the shifting of pollution location or in the
potential introduction of unpredictability in regional environmental conditions would require
explicit safeguards. That is, for example, if waste water discharges were transferred between two
different locations as part of permit trading, safeguards would be needed to protect the interests
of persons living along or using the water affected. If various types of interregional emissions
trading are allowed, safeguards would be needed to assure that applicable local environmental
standards continued to be met. Hence, even a market-based system requires a regulatory
framework in order to function and thus is supplemental to such command and control
requirements.
Moral Opposition to Local Changes in Pollution
Closely related to the above, some environmental groups have opposed market approaches
on the grounds that any potentially damaging emissions should be eliminated. Thus there
shouldn't be a "right" to pollute which can be bought or sold. They argue that if it is possible to
reduce emissions at a given source, the source should not be allowed to buy emission rights from
some other source located in a different area, since the local area would continue to bear
View Page Image


CRS-31
avoidable pollution. On the other hand, regulations give one the "right" to pollute also by
meeting the given standard.
Measurement and Monitoring
A major technical and cost challenge for greater reliance on incentives is monitoring of
compliance, particularly for the cases of tradeable permits and less so for taxes on effluents or
emissions. By focusing on performance rather than on what hardware a company has installed,
enforcement difficulties increase.
Systems of monitoring are both necessary and likely to be more complex and expensive
than for a performance- or technology-based approach. With the latter, regulators know
approximately what abatement levels are being achieved and where. To actually measure
pollution levels from specific sources in order to impose charges requires regular monitoring or
self-reporting with periodic verification. For air emissions, for example, most sources do not
have continuous emissions monitoring, nor are all potentially controlled pollutants monitored.
Such monitoring is only required on new sources and coal burning utilities for sulfur dioxide
control purposes. For existing sources, compliance is generally determined by ambient
concentrations as measured by ground monitors. Individual stack monitors would be imperative
to comprehensively monitor compliance with an emissions tax or for systems of potentially
widely-traded emissions. For the SO2 allowance trading system under the Clean Air Act
Amendments, continuous emissions monitoring is a requirement.
On the other hand, taxes on inputs (such as carbon content of coal) do not require any
extensive monitoring or administrative systems.
Complexity Of Nonconventional Pollutants
The complexity of nonconventional pollutants (i.e., toxics, pesticides, etc.) as well as the
complexity of their sources likely renders tax or charge systems for other than revenue purposes
an extreme challenge in most situations, since authorities would have to set charges for and
monitor a vast number of pollutants and sources. Taxing substances on the input side presents
fewer problems, particularly since companies would normally have transaction data on which
to base charges. For example, proposals for reauthorization of the Clean Water Act include
charges on certain types of toxic chemicals based on a rating of their degree of toxicity.
Institutional Capability and Authority
As stated above, the Federal government has the potential legal authority to use taxes as
a policy tool for influencing private-sector behavior. Some environmental statutes, specifically
the recently amended Clean Air Act, and less so the Clean Water Act, also contain varying
degrees of encouragement or limitations on use of market-type approaches. Beyond the legal
question, Federal, State, and local governments would likely require additional resources,
experience, and capabilities to structure, manage, and enforce certain types of market-based
approaches.
Specifically, capabilities would be needed to structure and facilitate market-type
transactions while avoiding the chilling effect of excessive regulations, oversight, and third party
intervention. Monitoring systems, inter jurisdictional coordination, enforcement authority and
capability, technical analytic staffs, among other resources would be important in supporting less
centralized, market-oriented management systems.
View Page Image


CRS-32
Market Imperfections
The potential for trading overcontrol of pollution or credits to facilitate environmental
management requires well organized markets for trading. If buyers and sellers are few,
information is limited, property rights are not well-defined, transaction rules are cumbersome and
time-consuming, if the public can intervene at multiple points in the decision process, or a few
large organizations can manipulate availability and price of permits, then the potential for trading
is unlikely to be realized or to improve environmental management.
Thus, for pollution or credit trading programs, information and exchange mechanisms
(public or private) would need to evolve quickly to help bring interested parties together. In
many situations, responsible agencies would have to have the capability to monitor market
development and to deal with possible problems of market dominance by very large
organizations or other serious noncompetitive actions.
Regional Definitions and Boundaries
A difficult problem for many of the incentive options is inequities at jurisdictional
boundaries, though this problem also holds for many current environmental regulations. For
example, if input taxes on polluting substances were used, strong incentives exist for avoiding
the cost by doing business in neighboring jurisdictions not using similar programs. Differences
in administrative and legal requirements across jurisdictional lines may also reduce the appeal
and potentials of some of these approaches.
Compliance Versus Abatement Costs
One of the major concerns with some of these approaches is the cost burden on companies.
Systems that involve government auctioning of tradeable permits or payment of effluent charges
particularly raise this problem.
While auction of permits or pollution taxes theoretically achieve the least cost allocation
of pollution abatement expenditures, companies would also pay for the market costs of permits
or pay pollution charges on unabated pollution. This money is paid to the government and is
considered a transfer within society from a social or economic perspective. However, for
companies the combination of spending on pollution abatement as well as permits or effluent
taxes is usually more costly than meeting the requirements for uniform treatment
Understandably, options having this result are vigorously opposed by industry.
Cross-Media Effects
Raising the cost of one means of waste disposal or disposal of one particular pollutant can
often result in diversion of pollutants to other untaxed or uncontrolled environmental media. As
with current regulatory systems, anything less than a comprehensive approach, particularly with
toxic or hazardous substances, invites diversion to other media or even illegal dumping.
View Page Image


CRS-33
INSTITUTIONAL CONSIDERATIONS IN IMPLEMENTATION
The beginning of market-based approaches to environmental protection in the United States
is accompanied by a growing number of proposals for greater use of these types of policy tools.
Such options are now solidly on the environmental agenda, even though they face significant
institutional and practical obstacles to early or easy application. The challenge to adoption of
such techniques is the extent to which these mechanisms can be at odds with other important
imperatives, authorities, jurisdictions, and practical implementation and management needs.
THE ROLE FOR MARKET APPROACHES IN A REGULATORY CONTEXT
The extent to which market-based mechanisms might ultimately become a major feature
of environmental management policy is subject to a wide range of debate. Such mechanisms do,
however, offer a pragmatic vehicle for accomplishing several things effectively, either as a
supplement to prescriptive regulatory systems or as freestanding systems. These systems offer
at least the following general features which can allow for incremental refinements in existing
environment and resource management systems:
Regulatory Efficiencies - Introduction of flexibility in meeting some facility emission
standards or regional ambient quality standards resulting in lower direct compliance
costs or lower indirect costs due to a less cumbersome compliance process;
Phase out or Phase Down Mechanisms - Introduction of flexibility and cost savings
in meeting a national or regional pollution constraint where trading of emission
sources does not create local violation of health-based standards;
A Way for Internalizing External Costs - Signalling a societal desire for reduction in
the overall consumption of environmentally damaging substances or activities by
raising their costs to the user in situations where other forms of environmental control
are impractical, too costly, less effective, or counter to other values such as individual
freedoms. Taxing cigarettes or alcohol are cases in point at a personal level. Part of
the motivation for a gasoline tax seems to fall in this category.
Not unrelated to these features is the potential for revenue to pay for environmental
protection efforts or to serve other fiscal needs.
The possibilities for less costly or more effective environmental management from adopting
these types of innovations are widely argued and illustrated in academic and other policy
literature. What is less often examined are the issues for implementation within both the
legislative process and the institutional constraints of the Federal system. This section looks at
general implementation issues for three generic approaches and their variations. It also briefly
reviews other market- conditioning mechanisms such as information requirements, liability
assignment, best management practices, and pricing polices.
The approaches include:

1)Taxing pollution, polluting activities, or polluting inputs;


View Page Image


CRS-34
2)Allowing businesses to trade a set amount of pollution or other constraint on business
activity (a fixed amount of sulfur dioxide emissions, recycled paper content in
newsprint, etc.) among themselves in order to achieve gains from trade and thus
achieve lower compliance costs;
3)Using a deposit-refund mechanism to create incentives to recycle or properly dispose
of containers, and some hazardous substances or contaminated equipment;
4)Changing how individuals and businesses approach market transactions that may
affect the environment by increasing available information, by internalizing risks
through liability assignment, by pricing policies, and by means such as contracts or
other types of agreements.
TAXING POLLUTION
The concept of taxing pollution is simple. The political and management reality of "pure"
pollution taxes, however, is far from simple. Indeed, the pragmatic side of pollution taxes
suggests only limited circumstances where convergent interests, policy needs, and institutional27
capability may make some variation of this approach a part of environmental management.
As discussed below, it is the variations on the theme that may hold more policy interest than the
conceptual case proposed by some.
The General Case
Pollution damages important human values (health, aesthetics, materials, or the functioning
of ecosystems indirectly necessary for human welfare). Thus, not all of the costs (both monetary
and nonmonetary) of polluting activities are reflected in the prices of the respective goods or
service. This means that damages to other values could be reduced or avoided if less of the good
or service were produced, the production or consumption involved more benign technology, or
defensive efforts were made to counter the pollution.
In these circumstances, economists recommend a tax on the pollution from the activity or
product which causes damages to other values so that price signals the full social cost to the user
(private cost of production plus monetary value of external damages). The level of the tax is set
so that enough economic units (producers or consumers) modify their various behavior
(consumption, fuel choice, technology, chemical use or design, etc.) to just balance the
incremental value of the reduction in external damages from pollution with the incremental costs
of reduction. In this scheme, those who find it cheaper to reduce pollution than pay taxes do so.
They pay taxes on any remaining pollution their activity causes. Those who find it more
expensive to make changes than pay the tax do so and thus continue polluting.
In theory, a tax set at the proper level will result in a reduction in pollution where costs of
reduction are balanced with the benefits of such reductions, that is, where incremental costs of
reduction and incremental benefits of reduction are just equal. Such an arrangement implies a
great deal of information on polluting activities, the damages such activities may cause, and how
27For example, see: U.S. General Accounting Office. Environmental Protection:
Implications of Using Pollution taxes for Supplement Regulation. GAO/RCED-93-13.
Washington, D.C., 1993.
View Page Image


CRS-35
individuals value those damages. Such information would be used by public authorities to
structure and administer pollution taxes.
Implementing Pollution Taxes
While some countries have used variations of pollution taxes to help manage water quality
for some river systems, no pollution tax conceived as a method of balancing incremental control
costs with incremental social benefits has been attempted to date. There are good reasons for this
and include the following considerations:
Credibility of Information
Estimates of monetary benefits necessary to justify tax levels cannot be developed in a
practical and systematically defendable way. Economists have methods for estimating
willingness to pay to reduce pollution, but such methods are experimental at best and not
operational in terms of governmental obligations for protecting public health and other
environmental values. Thus, there is no publicly acceptable way to measure the monetary
benefits of most forms of pollution reduction that would allow defendable methods for setting
a tax. Instead, where taxes have been proposed as an alternative to direct regulation, it has been
more along the lines of how high should a tax be to induce incremental expenditures by
industries in order to achieve a desired reduction in pollution with the tax.
Limited Applicability
The type of pollutants for which optimal taxes are usually proposed tend to be those that
do not have long term or irreversible human or environmental consequences. The standard case
is organic forms of water pollution which can be assimilated and broken down by normal
bacterial processes. The more complex pollution problems, however, relate to certain toxics and
pesticides which are long lasting, bioaccumulate and cycle in the environment. These pollutants
have diffuse and often hard to understand consequences, which often show up first in aquatic and
related ecosystems. Using optimal taxes to manage the myriad compounds that are potentially
damaging presupposes immense analytical, monitoring and enforcement capability which is not
currently the case.
Use of Tax Revenues
The disposition of revenues from taxes on pollution raises several difficult practical issues.
If pollution is taxed in some way (pollutants, inputs, activity) to bring about its overall reduction,
three questions arise. First, who receives the revenue? Second, what happens as revenue from
the tax declines as pollution declines?; i.e., what happens to the revenue base? Third, how are
taxes adjusted for inflation to keep the economic incentive constant in real terms? While these
questions can be easily answered in concept, answers within the Federal system pose significant
problems. Interests affected by taxes typically like to see benefits from such taxes, for example
the highway gasoline tax going for highway construction. Answers also affect the
macroeconomic impacts of such taxes.
Data Availability
Taxing pollution assumes the availability of comprehensive and precise monitoring systems
which do not currently exist and would be expensive to install, maintain, and verify. Unless self
reporting is used or more readily measurable entities such as inputs (for example, high sulfur coal
View Page Image


CRS-36
rather than sulfur emissions) are taxed, taxes would require expensive monitoring in order to
ensure accurate reporting.
Other Ways of Using Taxes
Accepting the practical difficulties of using taxes to precisely manage environmental
quality on a location specific-basis, there are other roles that taxes, charges, or fees can play.
Fees already serve as a basis for partial or complete financing of some environmental
protection programs. Fees are levied on regulated entities to recover some or all of the costs of
administering Federal, State, or local environmental protection programs. The level of fees must
reflect the cost of administrative services performed meaning that fees seldom will provide any
strong incentive for reducing pollution beyond the regulatory requirements.
Between the financing of environmental protection programs with fees and the precise
taxing of pollution to achieve an essentially unknowable optimal reduction probably lies a more
pragmatic role for taxes in implementing already determined social goals. This role evolves from
using taxes to implement a policy for which a consensus on achieving a specific reduction target
has been obtained. For example, the acid rain control program could have had a tax imposed that
achieved a 10 million ton reduction in SO2, but a permit program was chosen instead.
The use of taxes in these circumstances may have several purposes not necessarily related
to environmental protection but possibly modifying behavior sufficiently to produce some
reduction in polluting activity. Such taxes may raise general or dedicated revenue, send a signal
on level of consumption, possibly be used to offset other revenue sources, or serve other
purposes such as capture of windfall gains where other environmental regulations are driving up
product prices.
The tax on chlorofluorocarbons (CFCs) and proposals for an increase in the Federal
gasoline tax are primary examples of how taxes are or could be applied as part of broader policy
packages. In the case of CFCs, the tax adds incentive to find substitutes and speed phase-out,
but most observers see its imposition as much as a way to capture some of the price runup due
to phase-out and to raise revenue. Proposals for large increases in the gasoline tax are packaged
with any number of motivations including deficit reduction; increased energy security through
reduced consumption of oil and long run incentives to increase equipment efficiency; as a general
premium to signal the social costs of auto use including air pollution, congestion, and accidents;
and as an incentive to shift toward alternative fuels, among others.
A tax on carbon dioxide or more precisely, a tax on carbon content of fuel, has also been
proposed as one possible response to forthcoming treaty commitments by the United States on
global climate change. The level of such a tax would not be set based on an unknowable value
of marginal damages from future climate change. Rather, a target for reduction would need to
be related to incremental costs of reduction and the tax set at the incremental reduction cost. A
large amount of revenue would be raised which opens the possibility of offsetting other taxes or
spending areas so as to minimize the immediate economic impact. The Clinton Administration
and the Rio Declaration at the 1992 Earth Summit have committed the country to stabilization
of greenhouse gases at 1990 levels by the year 2000. A carbon equivalent tax could be set at the
marginal cost of achieving that policy goal. Other possibilities for energy-based taxes related
to climate change include a tax on Btu content of fuel, which shifts the initial costs away from
fuels such as coal and may spread the distributional consequences.
View Page Image


CRS-37
In contrast to a precise pollution tax based on balancing regional environmental benefits
and control costs, a broad based tax serving multiple objectives is likely to have widespread and
highly visible equity or distributional consequences. To the extent that such taxes have
environmental purposes, the objective is to affect levels of consumption and possibly long run
technology or product design and function. In most cases, making consumption more expensive
will disproportionately burden lower income individuals. Opposition to a generalized gasoline
tax is partially along these lines. As with all taxes, some relief to lower income individuals can
be realized through refundable credits or means tests, though the administrative burden increases.
Proposed gasoline taxes fall into this category. Impacts from a carbon tax would be more
concentrated initially on coal producing regions, rail transportation, and coal using utilities in
terms of income and employment loss. The tax would also quickly be reflected in the rates of
coal-consuming electricity utilities, currently about sixty percent of total electric generation.
TRADING OF POLLUTION REDUCTION OR OTHER RESOURCE
MANAGEMENT CONSTRAINTS
Another way to potentially reduce the costs of achieving environmental standards or other
resource management constraints is to allow regulated sources to trade the location and nature
of compliance among themselves. This is already done to some degree through EPA's air
emissions trading program and is a central feature of the acid rain control provisions of the 1990
Clean Air Act Amendments.
This type of mechanism is usually applicable only where the pollutant mixes uniformly and
is damaging over a broad geographical area. Under those circumstances, the point of control is
less important than is putting a limit on the total amount of pollution. As long as local health-
based standards are met, where in the region pollution is reduced is not important to overall
regional environmental quality.
The General Case
As with taxes, the economic logic of tradeable over control of pollution (or other
compliance obligations like recycled material content) within a binding limit on total emissions
is compelling. If reductions can be concentrated at those sources with the lowest costs, the total
economic cost will be less than if sources with differing costs are required to achieve equal
reductions. This least cost outcome is possible if each source is required to control damaging
activity at the specified rate of reduction, but then allowed to sell over control to or buy over
control from other enterprises. For those with low (incremental) costs of reduction, it pays to
over control and sell the excess reduction to enterprises that have high (incremental) costs, who
then are allowed to continue emitting pollutants. The end result is control at the required total
level of reduction. If site specific shifts in the source of damaging activity is not an issue, this
type of mechanism can be a cost-effective way to meet a variety of environmental and natural
resource management goals.
View Page Image


CRS-38
Implementing Tradeable Pollution or Other Compliance Requirements
Implementing any tradeable pollution system requires consideration of several important
institutional needs. These include:
Protecting Private Transactions
For there to be a market for pollution or other compliance over control, there has to be
security of underlying private obligations. This leads to two very strong necessary conditions
for development of a trading system. First, over control is essentially an investment and as such
must be viewed as "property" that belongs to the investing enterprise if there is to be any
reasonable incentive for trading. Government recognition and protection of that property is
essential for markets to develop. Second, government can facilitate market development by
minimizing the transactions costs of trading. The less encumbered with oversight and potential
vetoes by government authorities or other parties, the more likely that trading and cost saving28
potentials will be realized.
Meeting Public Purposes
On the other side of the coin, there also has to be accountability for the public purpose
being served. Thus, most "open-market" trading systems would have to be monitored and
regulated possibly more than traditional technology or performance-based command and control
systems. 29
This level of information is necessary in order to verify that over control has occurred and
can be sold to other emission sources or third parties (for example brokers or middlemen).
Advances in technology may make this feature less costly over time and there are surrogate ways
for estimating how much control is achieved. Nonetheless, operation of a trading system
necessarily must be information intensive if authorities are to meet statutorily mandated goals.
While voluntary reporting of reductions and trades is possible, it may invite bogus
transactions and program failure. Any voluntary reporting system would require consistent
random auditing or monitoring to verify reported transactions. Such a system might also invite
lawsuits from environmental groups challenging lack of progress or performance by responsible
State or local implementing agencies.
28For an excellent discussion of the transactions and enforcement issues facing these types of
trading programs see: Dwyer, John P. The Use of Market Incentives in Controlling Air
Pollution: California's Marketable Permits Program. Ecology Law Quarterly. Vol. 20, No.

1, 1993. pp. 103-117.


29Implementation of the sulfur dioxide allowance trading system under the 1990 Clean Air
Act Amendments may have annual costs other than direct compliance between of $1 to $1.5
billion which is 15 to 25 percent of estimated annual compliance costs. These noncompliance
costs include the mandated continuous emissions monitors for all regulated sources as well as
other transactions and tracking costs, permit fees, and various sales costs. For a full discussion
of these issues see: U.S. Library of Congress. Congressional Research Service. Implementing
SO2 Allowance Trading: Implications of Transaction Costs and Taxes. Report No. 93-313
ENR, by Larry B. Parker and Donald W. Keifer. Washington, 1993.
View Page Image


CRS-39
Achieving Equity
Implementing a trading system on top of existing command and control systems raises
challenges as to how much credit each entity should receive for past efforts. Inequities arise
quickly where differing degrees of control have been previously achieved. Giving each source
a percentage of its remaining emissions is inherently unfair to those who have already invested
in control, or who have very modern facilities with low emissions by design. The fairest system
probably involves distributing emission rights in proportion to pre-control emissions levels. This
covers the situation where sources have made equipment or fuel changes and are cleaner than the
new requirements because it gives them over control to sell. It still leaves an inequity when new
low-pollution technology has been built into an industrial system for a variety of reasons, the
source has no pre-control baseline, and is cleaner than the new standards require. Sources in
such situations could be forced to buy emissions rights to expand operations when they are
already cleaner than any other source.
Thus, implementing emission trading systems requires political decisions and regulatory
machinery not unlike current programs. Title IV of the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments
establishing the sulfur dioxide allowance trading system for coal-burning electric utilities
illustrates this concern. Passage required complex allocation systems to accommodate concerns
over regional cost burdens and equity as well as operational flexibility. Some of the allocation
formulas reflect site-specific concerns (e.g., local politics). This as yet untested national trading
system, however, may not be a representative test since it is being implemented within the State-
regulated electric utility system. At a minimum, the oversight of State regulatory commissions
on profit oriented utility activities raises questions about the degree of innovation and flexibility
the SO2 allowance trading mechanism will ultimately show.30
Taxing Profits
If contracting parties agree to an exchange of over control or over compliance, income is
generated by the seller and costs are incurred by the buyer. How these buying and selling
transactions are treated for tax purposes by the IRS will have an important bearing on the
strength of the incentive to invest in over control and on the incentive to buy over control as
opposed to controlling to the required standard. If net income generated by selling over control
is taxed at the marginal corporate rate, then the amount of over control forthcoming will be
reduced in total since marginal investments in over control must stand a rate of return test against
other corporate investments. How over control is achieved may also have a bearing on whether
a depreciable asset or an expensable cost is being offered to other parties. If the over control
bought by a purchasing enterprise is treated as a service regardless of the method by which it is
generated, no differential incentive is created. On the other hand, if over control is treated as a
depreciable capital expense purchased for its useful or physical life, allowed rates of depreciation
may affect the choices made. In particular, allowing a faster write-off than the actual annual use
would create a financial advantage because the early recovery of the investment could shelter
other income from taxes.31
30 For a discussion of experience, pro and con, with the allowance trading system to date see:
U.S. Senate Committee on Environment and Public Works. Three Years Later: Report Card
on the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments. Washington, D.C. November 15, 1993.
31See for example: Parker, Larry B. et. al. Clean Air Act Allowance Trading.
(continued...)
View Page Image


CRS-40
Ways of Using Tradeable Permits or Other Over
Performance on Standards
The contractual nature of pollution trading and the oversight nature of all levels of
government in assuring adherence to environmental requirements, other jurisdictional needs, or
political requirements suggests that trading is likely to be more practical in some circumstances
than others. From experience and trends to date some of these general circumstances may
include the following:
Creating Regional Bubbles
Current air emissions trading mechanisms operate within tightly drawn rules which limit
how and where trades of uniformly mixing air pollutants can take place. While the SO2
allowance trading system is designed to be national in scope, whether it moves much beyond
bilateral trades under State public utility commission supervision remains to be seen. Because
over control involves private investment decisions that essentially create property rights and
because the obligation of local and State governments to avoid third party effects caused by
changing the location of specific pollution sources, most pollution trading seems likely to be tied
closely in location. If this is the direction of tradeable pollution control, it is a logical extension
of the bubble approach now used for individual plants.
Creating Cross-Trading
Cross trades involve buying environmental controls in an activity different from the
pollution source in order to create the right of the buying entity to avoid its own more costly
control expenditures.32 Examples include reforestation as CO2 offsets or buying up old cars to
reduce urban air pollution rather than controlling stationary sources. Although only a limited
number of cross-trades have been authorized or attempted to date, they are a frequent option in
proposals ranging from carbon dioxide control to solid waste recycling. Factors which will
probably determine which options have potential for implementation include:
Unimportance of the specific location of reduction within a control region;
Ease of verification of compliance, both for public sector purposes and for purposes
of private contractual arrangements;
Large enough cost differentials to offset additional monitoring and contractual costs
for control outside of the buying entity; and
31(...continued)
Environmental Law. Vol. 21, No. 4II, 1991. pp. 2051-2053; and Parker, Larry B. and Kiefer,
Donald W. Implementing SO2 Allowance Trading: Implications of Transactions Costs and
Taxes. U.S. Library of Congress. Congressional Research Service. CRS Report 93-313 ENR.
March 1993. pp. 6-8.
32See for example The U.S. Library of Congress. Congressional Research Service. Coal
Market Effects of CO2 Control Strategies as Embodied in H.R. 1086 and H.R. 2663. Report
No. 91-883 ENR, by Larry Parker, Washington, December, 1991.
View Page Image


CRS-41
Lack of other more cost-effective options to meet pollution standards for regulated
sources.
Achieving Cost-Sharing
Tradeable permits can serve to share the cost burden where pollution generation occurs in
one area with environmental damages occurring in a geographically different area. The sulfur
dioxide allowance trading mechanism under the Amendments gives regions that would benefit
from reduced acid rain, mainly the Northeast, long run reasons to buy allowances from coal
burning electric utilities in the Midwest. Through such financial exchanges, the costs of over
control in the Midwest ultimately may be reduced and the costs of compliance in the Northeast
raised, helping to spread the financial burden more evenly between the regions. However, in the
near term, there has been no activity along these lines.
Circumstances for implementing such broad scale cost sharing may be unique to problems
such as acid rain, but that example does point to several general conditions necessary for
successful programs. These include:
A significant one-way contribution of total pollution in the receiving region from the
other region, based on prevailing weather or hydrologic conditions;
Pollutants or other attributes that are not an immediate threat to human health;
Emission sources that already operate under permit or could readily be put under
permit systems for the pollutant;
Relatively similar levels of economic activity between the regions but with
differences in the cost structure for controlling pollution; e.g., large economies of
scale with low incremental abatement costs for industry in the generating region and
more diffuse, high incremental cost sources in the receiving region;
A cap on total damaging activity between the two regions that is significantly below
current or expected levels due to growth.
Despite the early hopes for the allowance trading program, the initial phase has seen only
a handful of trades, mainly among Midwest utilities. The first auction of allowances resulted in
purchases of all allowances offered by the EPA but few takers for allowances offered by33
utilities. Thus the ideal circumstances listed above for broad scale interregional permit trading
raise some important questions in the operational world of most large scale industrial sectors.
Creating Transitional or Phase-out Efficiencies
Trading of permits for industries which must eliminate a substance can ease the transition
and costs. Trading of timing or location of compliance is appropriate where elements within the
industry have widely differing phase-out costs. The often-cited example is the phase-down of
lead in gasoline accomplished through a tradeable lead credit program between refiners. Refiners
33 For a general discussion of these issues see: Parker, Larry. Implementing Acid Rain
Legislation. CRS Issue Brief 91035. Congressional Research Service. U.S. Library of
Congress. Updated regularly
View Page Image


CRS-42
who had very high phase-out costs were able to buy credits from refiners who were able to
accelerate the phase-out at a low cost. This type of trading could serve under circumstances
similar to the refinery sector given the following conditions:
The potential for or history of cooperation and coordination of some operations
within the industry;
A long lead time so that planning for phase-out can be coordinated with other
planning needs;
Substantial differences in production costs and size between firms or plants.
View Page Image


CRS-43
DEPOSIT/REFUND
Beyond refundable deposits on beverage containers, many have proposed using this
mechanism for certain diffuse pollution sources where return for proper disposal or recycling is
environmentally important, but hard to achieve through traditional regulatory means.
This type of mechanism is applicable where the item of concern is durable or can be
contained and has some salvage or reuse value. Alternately, some are proposing that strong
incentives be created for recycling or proper disposal of certain types of hazardous materials by
requiring refundable deposits.34
The General Case
The success in reducing litter through deposit-refunds for beverage containers in several
States demonstrates the effectiveness for this mechanism to solve certain types of environmental
problems. Unlike tradeable permits, this mechanism is straight forward in concept and initial
implementation for three reasons. First, the goals and the method are easily understood by the
public. If the deposit is large enough relative to the purchase price of the product, the user or
others have strong incentives to return containers. Second, once enacted, implementing a
deposit-refund system is largely up to the private sector. While business practices must be
altered and some manufacturing employment may be lost, recycling and other transactions jobs
are created under these types of programs. Third, the types of products where this is applicable
are typically not adulterated or contaminated by use nor are the containers of high enough value
to induce counterfeiting or large scale fraud in order to capture refunds.
Thus, for standard recyclable products such as beverage containers, the State-by-State
implementation that has occurred, by most reports has not caused major dislocations in container
manufacturing or disruptions in retail distribution and has therefore been credited with
measurable improvements in litter problems and increased levels of recycling.
Implementing Deposit Refund Systems
Extending deposit-refund systems to materials other than beverage containers, as some
propose, raises several practical challenges. The severity of these challenges pose depends on
the type of product or material under consideration, and in particular, the engineering and
material requirements for either recycling or disposing of reclaimed materials. Though each area
has its own unique concerns, several implementing issues hold to varying degrees for all of the
various candidates for deposit and refunds. These include:
34 For example see: Macauley, Molly K. et. al. Using Economic Incentives to Regulate
Toxic Substances. Resources for the Future. Washington, D.C. 1992.
View Page Image


CRS-44
Durability
The durability or containability of the item or material - The lower the additional effort
(expenses and labor or personal time) to store, collect, handle, transport, and reprocess or dispose
of the material, the more attractive this mechanism becomes. Beverage containers would be at
one end of a continuum with some hazardous chemicals at the other. In between are problem
items such as batteries, tires, and pesticide containers to name current examples.
Cost-Competitive Recycling
The existence of, or strong potential for, cost-competitive recycling - The greater the
existing infrastructure for using or reprocessing the product or material, the more the
fundamental economics will drive implementation. Deposit refund coupled with marketable
recycling quotas could provide double incentives in some situations as would deposit-refund
coupled with a product tax on new materials.
Existing Information Systems
The existence of well-developed information management and tracking systems to which
deposit-refund information needs can be easily added - The more fully developed product
information is, the less disruptive additional record keeping is likely to be, making that part of
implementation less costly.
Economies of Scale
The existence of economies of scale in treatment and disposal of hazardous materials - The
greater the cost-economies that can be captured through centralized treatment, the more likely
a market-based deposit-refund approach would be attractive compared to other more restrictive
control programs.
Ease of Verification
The capability to distinguish on a cost-effective basis qualifying returns from counterfeits
in order to avoid exploitation of the system. This is particularly necessary where hard-to-analyze
hazardous waste would be involved or where imports from other jurisdictions or countries could
be used to capture refund monies.
Strength of Monetary and Nonmonetary Incentives
The inconvenience issues in deposit-refund systems can be a greater issue for users than
the need to pay deposits - While deposit-refund systems may appear as a cost-effective way to
achieve some types of environmental management objectives, time costs and inconvenience for
those affected must also be considered in any comprehensive appraisal. The acceptance and
success of any systems that rely on voluntary compliance will likely depend on three factors:
The size of the deposit relative to the value of the product; the larger the deposit, the
greater the likely rate of redemption by either initial purchasers or secondary markets
that collect and return for income purposes;
The size of expenses incurred in storing and returning containers;
View Page Image


CRS-45
The degree of inconvenience and time incurred (including disruption of normal
routines; time needed to collect, clean, handle, and transport containers; intrusion on
storage and space management needs of homes and businesses; and administrative
and record keeping changes that may be at odds with existing practices).
Ways of Using Deposit-Refund
A number of proposals for using deposit-refund suggest the potentials for this mechanism
and also illustrate the challenges to effective implementation. Applications discussed in several
recent studies include lead acid batteries, lubricating oil, industrial solvents, and pesticide
containers among others. The major motivation behind deposit-refund proposals for these types
of products is local environmental management problems that current disposal practices may
pose, in particular significant contributions to nonpoint source water pollution and solid waste
management. Because the types of activities contributing to these environmental problems are
diffuse and numerous, the reach of traditional regulatory tools is often limited or unduly
burdensome, leading some to advocate market-based approaches such as deposit-refund. The
few operational examples of these types of mechanisms and several proposed options allow some
general observations about circumstances for possible application of these tools. These examples
are discussed in detail later in the report and general cases are discussed here.
High Volume Nonhazardous Materials with Recycling Potential Beyond beverage containers,
there may be other household containers which consumers could conveniently bring back to a
retail outlet and which might have the potential for a deposit-refund approach. Since most non
beverage containers are not associated with littering problems, use of this approach would be a
way to accelerate the rate of recycling for potentially valuable materials. In practice, use of this
tool would probably only be practical at a State or national level as a supplement to reduce
demands on landfill or other disposal capacity.
Highly Toxic Low Volume Materials with High Treatment Costs
Many of the proposals for extending deposit-refund deal with categories of chemicals that
pose special disposal problems. Such chemicals may be treated most efficiently in large
sophisticated disposal systems requiring economies of scale in order to be cost-effective. Short
of mandating use of such facilities by regulated industries, a less intrusive way of increasing the
control on special types of toxic chemicals could be to require large deposits at the point of sale.
These deposits would be refunded upon return of certifiable spent chemicals or their byproducts
to a regional disposal facility. Such chemicals would have to be used in reasonably closed
industrial processes or be readily managed for final containerization and return to a disposal
facility. Verification of purchase would be necessary to avoid problems of counterfeit returns.
Contaminated Products or Equipment With High Disposal Costs
Similar to the above, products such as used lead acid batteries, other electrical equipment,
and contaminated containers are being or could be included in deposit-refund systems. These
products often pose landfill and other disposal problems and are hard to regulate because the
products are so widely used. In contrast to counterfeiting issues for containerized toxics, a key
issue for this type is the incentive for theft if the deposit is too high relative to the product price.
This potential raises the need for accurate documentation which in turn increases the
inconvenience cost to participants. Also challenging are the product handling concerns where
consumers may be disinclined to transport used equipment very far, necessitating numerous
View Page Image


CRS-46
pickup points. Final disposal of such contaminated products implies treatment capability as with
the above example.
Widely Used Substances with No Acceptable On-site Disposal Methods
Used motor oil is the main example in this category. This type of approach could be used
for high-volume substances that are used in equipment but not consumed in the process; that are
potentially harmful to the environment; and that are prone to widespread improper disposal to
land, water, or air. Chlorofluorocarbons used in cooling equipment would be an example. While
deposit refund could be one tool for bringing improper CFC disposal under control, phase-out
and product taxation are the methods Congress has chosen for dealing with this area.
Major challenges for this use of deposit-refund, both for used motor oil and any other
proposed substances, exist both at the user end and in the ultimate market for reuse and recycling.
At the user end, unless the deposit is large, the inconvenience of collection, storage, and transport
to a receiving station may work against significant compliance. As with other deposit-refund
substances, final use depends on the physical recycling potential, market conditions for such
materials, in particular price relative to virgin materials, and the degree of contamination of the
materials which may render them useless or require an extensive infrastructure for processing.
OTHER MARKET STRENGTHENING ACTIONS
Beyond proposed market-based mechanisms such as those above, Federal and State
governments have strengthened information and liability requirements for certain products and
disposal activities in order to improve environmental management. Also, education on best
management practices can be a cost-effective way of improving resource management.
Specific examples of these more traditional methods for guiding profit-oriented economic
activity towards more broadly desirable outcomes are described at various points later in the
report. Some general issues of implementation are identified briefly below.
Information
A traditional role played by government is the provision of information to in order to
inform and ideally improve consumer and business decision-making. Provision of a variety of
economic statistics is an obvious example. A century of support to farm management through
Federal extension services is another.
By giving consumers, businesses, and organized interest groups more accurate information
about products or activities that affect the environment or human health, both the private sector
and the political process ideally can make better informed decisions. This type of government
activity is typically undertaken on the premise that some kinds of broadly beneficial information
is a public good which profit-oriented enterprises do not provide because full costs cannot be
recovered or because it may be counter to their commercial interests.
In the environmental area, government is involved in both education as well as mandatory
disclosure of various types of use, disposal, or resource-status information accompanying either
products, processes, chemicals, or sometimes asset sales. Both the Federal and State
governments have passed laws broadening industry information disclosure requirements. For
example, Section 313 of Title III of the Superfund Amendments and Reauthorization Act (P.L.
99-499) requires manufacturers and users of toxic chemicals to provide detailed information to
View Page Image


CRS-47
the public on the amounts of such chemicals stored on-site and released to the environment.
Proposition 65 in California by direct voter initiative uses mandatory information provision along
with regulation to help reduce an individual's exposure to potentially harmful substances. New
Jersey's Environmental Cleanup Responsibility Act requires facilities dealing with hazardous
wastes to either verify sites are clean or submit a cleanup plan to the State when the property is
sold or transferred.
In mandating information disclosure, several implementation issues bear on the efficacy
of such requirements and the impacts they may have on business and consumer decisions.
Factors that may affect the usefulness of additional publicly available information can
include:
The complexity of the subject, particularly where significant scientific uncertainty
exists making risk or hazard characterizations difficult and time-consuming for users
to interpret;
The potential for abuse of such information for political purposes, causing damage
to product or business reputations; and
The credibility of the information source.
Factors that may affect business and consumer decisions can include:
The cost of producing reliable information on health or environmental risks from
products or substances;
The risk to business from disclosure of trade or competitively-sensitive information;
The increased awareness of communities to potential risks and adverse environmental
effects which may increase the effect of moral suasion or public pressure on business
decision-making.
On the latter point, according to some in industry, mandatory information disclosure
provisions may be a more powerful force for inducing changes in some industry practices than
any of the current trading or tax mechanisms. This perception is reinforced by a recent study
suggesting that the SARA Title III disclosure requirements are a strong force for industries to
improve their management of hazardous chemicals.35,36
Liability Assignment
The establishment of liability rules acts as an explicit incentive to businesses (or
individuals) to modify their operations or behavior in order to avoid paying judgements to parties
who may be damaged as a result of failures to meet standards or other regulations. This tool has
35Carlin, Alan. Op. Cit. p 6-5.
36For the industry study see: Baram, Michael S., Dillon, Patricia S., and Ruffle, Betsy.
Managing Chemical Risks: Corporate Response to Sara Title III. The Center for
Environmental Management, Tufts University. May 1990.
View Page Image


CRS-48
been used extensively for disposers of hazardous chemicals under the financial responsibility
provisions of both Superfund and the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act. At the State
level, an example is Connecticut's 1982 Potable Drinking Water law which follows the principle
of strict liability for groundwater contamination.
While this tool has been used aggressively in recent years, it typically does not require the
innovation and institution building that the mechanisms described above do. As such, liability
assignments impose contingent costs on businesses in order to induce behavioral changes to
avoid such costs. Liability assignment can thus serve as an alternative to more direct
intervention.
The implementation issues in liability assignment are complex and the subject of extensive
analysis in the legal and economic professions. General issues in implementation may include:
How favorable the conditions are for a commercial insurance market to develop in
order for regulated businesses to balance risk minimization with affordable financial
protection in the event of an accident. In particular, thin markets with limited risk
experience may limit the availability of commercial insurance, which would create
especially difficult compliance problems for smaller businesses which cannot self-
insure.
How much the liability exposure is to financial risks beyond financially feasible
preventive and insurance capabilities;
How targeted the liability assignment is to aspects of a business which will produce
improvements in environmental management;
How detectable violations of standards are that would trigger enforcement and
liability obligations.
Best Management Practices
One other market-conditioning tool is best management practices, used most often in
conjunction with farm programs. These are attempts to educate users on operational practices
that minimize wastage and that promote broader land use or environmental benefits. Some
environmental management issues - particularly in the area of nonpoint source water pollution
related to fertilizers, toxics, and pesticides - stem, in part, from relatively low input costs
compared to the value added by their use. Under circumstances where labor is expensive and
such inputs are cheap, there is little incentive to manage the use of such substances precisely.
This is particularly the case if such changes increase labor costs and competitors do not follow
suit. Ideally, education on best management practices can produce operational savings that more
than offset additional costs or inconvenience of such changes. Without that incentive,
operational changes that reduce the use of environmentally harmful substances or that alter other
operational practices are not likely to be accepted voluntarily.
View Page Image


CRS-49
CURRENT U.S. APPROACHES
Experience with market based programs to this point reflects efforts to fit practical
approaches to evolving environmental and natural resource management problems. Most current
environmental protection policy, as reflected in the main Federal laws, is based foremost on
protection of public health; on use of existing administrative structures and facility permitting
processes; on predictability in implementation; and on reasonable consistency of effort for
similar classes of regulated entities.
There are any number of ways to classify the various current market-type approaches.
However, the public-sector management perspective described previously offers a framework
that bears on what has ultimately been authorized by Congress and implemented by the
responsible agencies. Current market-based programs are grouped here by the following policy
objectives:
Achieving Regional/Local Regulatory Efficiency;
Meeting National Pollution Reduction or Phase-Out Requirements Through Trading;
and,
Internalizing Social Costs Through Nonregulatory Means.
ACHIEVING REGIONAL/LOCAL REGULATORY EFFICIENCY
Examples in this category include various refinements to the implementing regulations
under the Clean Air and Clean Water Acts. These refinements serve to ease the burden on
industry by increasing the flexibility of compliance. The Environmental Protection Agency's air
emissions trading program is the most often cited-example in the U.S. In the water area,
programs for the Fox River in Wisconsin and Dillon Reservoir in Colorado have been
established.
Emissions Trading Program
Within the command-and-control structure of the Clean Air Act (CAA), EPA has attempted
over the years to introduce some flexibility to the implementation process. Before passage of the
1990 Amendments, EPA developed four market-based schemes to assist polluters in meeting the
requirements of the CAA at less cost. These are referred to as offsets, bubbles, banking, and
netting.
Offsets. The offset policy resulted from the pending failure of many regions to
achieve the National Ambient Air Quality Standards (NAAQS) by 1977. In 1976,
EPA, faced with the prospect of placing a construction ban on new sources in
nonattainment areas, proposed to allow new sources to be located in a nonattainment
area if the new sources installed Best Available Control Technology (BACT) and
obtained offsets from other facilities in the area so that the area's aggregate emissions
of the offending pollutant declined. In effect, the policy reduces pollution at existing
sources by making the owners of prospective new facilities pay for the reduction.
View Page Image


CRS-50
Placing the cost burden on new clean facilities rather than on existing sources which
are polluting is one criticism of the offset policy. By making new facilities more
expensive, modernization and technological advancement is impeded. In this
manner, the offset policy does not reverse the regulatory system's bias against new
sources as manifested in the New Source Performance Standards (NSPS).
Bubbling. In 1979, EPA proposed a bubble scheme. Bubbling permits a facility
with multiple emission sources to sum those sources and treat them as a single
source. Hence, the owners are free to achieve necessary reductions at any
combination of the facility's emission sources as long as the aggregate reduction is
achieved. The bubble is generally applicable only to existing sources, and no
interpollutant bubbling is allowed. (Proposals to expand bubbles, for example
between plants or between new and old sources, are highly controversial.)
Banking. In 1979, EPA promulgated regulations to bring the offset policy in
conformity with the 1977 Amendments. A third emissions trading scheme, banking,
was included in the regulations. Banking permits an emission source to save or
"bank" any emission reductions that were in excess of its regulatory requirement.
These banked reductions, called emission reduction credits, can be used by the
facility at a later date, or sold. In permitting the buying and selling of emission
reduction credits, banking facilitates the use of the first two trading schemes--offsets
and bubbles.
Previous to the 1977 Amendments, EPA attempts to introduce banking were declared
illegal; confiscation of emission reduction credits not used immediately was
considered a more rapid means of achieving the National Ambient Air Quality
Standards (NAAQS). The specific guidance given areas by the 1977 Amendments
was declared compatible with banking.
Banking is important because it provides a mechanism for polluters to effectively use
the offset and bubbling schemes discussed above. Also, banking provides some
incentive to "overcontrol"; that is, to control emissions more than the minimum legal
requirement. Opponents of banking feel that, in a nonattainment area, maximum
reductions should be mandated until compliance is achieved. Therefore, there should
be no excess reductions to bank.
Netting. Most analyses of trading schemes indicate that netting has resulted in the
greatest cost saving to industry. Netting began in 1974 and permits an existing
source to undergo a major modification without invoking the NSPS requirement if
the facility's aggregate emissions do not increase. Since under NSPS, new or major
modified sources must meet stringent requirements, netting's ability to reduce a
potentially significant control cost can result in significant savings to a facility's
owner.
View Page Image


CRS-51
The development and implementation of trading schemes in the U.S. have had a rocky road
for a variety of reasons.37 The Clean Air Act is focused on protecting human health with an
adequate margin of safety, and achieving this goal as rapidly as possible. The Act's primary
concession to economics is only requiring NSPS uniformly for new sources, and not requiring
such stringent controls on existing sources in attainment areas.
In some highly polluted areas, these health standards require very substantial pollutant
reductions which, coupled with the tight deadlines, leave little room for flexibility, and, therefore,
involve the greatest cost. It could be argued that, in nonattainment areas, if additional reductions
can be found at a source to offset emissions at another source, then the first source should be
required to meet that lower emission level and no offset granted; the urgency of the problem
requires maximum reductions. Indeed, the courts used variations on this argument to prevent
bubbling and netting in nonattainment areas previous to the 1977 Amendments.
A summary of emission trading activity is shown in table 3. As indicated, netting has
provided the bulk of estimated cost savings resulting from the various trading schemes. This is
not surprising because, by netting, a facility is avoiding NSPS--generally the most expensive
control method--compared with obtaining reductions from existing sources which could use
means other than NSPS to achieve reductions.
Offset Experience in Southern California
Southern California is often cited as having the most well developed emissions trading
market under the offsets program. As noted by Dwyer, however, only a small number of firms
completed trades with each other annually and such trades have been only a small part of
stationary source control programs.38 The Southern California experience is instructive for
understanding what may facilitate or hinder effective implementation of these types of programs.
37For example for a criticism of the experience with EPA's bubble program see: Doniger,
David D. The Dark Side of the Bubble. The Environmental Forum. July, 1985. Also a series
of opposing views on emissions trading in the March 1986 Environmental Forum (pp. 28-34).
38Dwyer, John P. The Use of Market Incentives in Controlling Air Pollution: California's
Marketable Permits Program. Ecology Law Quarterly. Vol. 20, No. 1, 1993. p. 108.
View Page Image


CRS-52
Table 3. Summary of Emissions Trading Activity*
EstimatedNumber of
InternalExternalEstimated Cost Savings
S c h e me Tra n sa c tio n s Tra n sa c tio n s (M illio n s $ )
Netting5,000-12,0000Permit Costs: $25-$300
Control Cost: $500-$12,000
Offsets 1 ,800 200 0
Bubbles:
Federal402$300
State890$135
Banking <100 <2 0 S mall
*Covering the mid-1970s through the mid-1980s
Source: Data from Hahn and Hester, 1986.
In 1976, the South Coast Air Quality Management District (SCAQMD) enacted Regulation
XII to require review of new stationary sources of air pollution. Emission reduction credits
(ERCs) were granted to companies that could prove real, permanent, quantifiable, enforceable,
and surplus emission reductions of reactive organic gasses (ROG), commonly known as volatile
organic compounds (VOCs), and nitrogen oxides (NOx). Originally, Regulation XII included a
contemporaneous reduction requirement specifying that offsetting credits must be used within
90 days of being generated. Although the timeframe for using credits was restrictive, there were
no geographical restrictions on where credits could be traded within the District. Many ERCs
were generated when plants shut down operations. Some were granted for achieving reductions
beyond that which were required by State and Federal standards. Between 1983 and 1990, 59
ERCs were issued to firms in the South Coast air basin; 31 were due to permanent shutdowns and
28 were issued for process changes that decreased emissions. During this period, 24 ERCs were
purchased and an additional 15 ERCs were used for offsetting increased emissions by the same39
owner's facility.
District Regulation XII was amended in June 1990. As a result of the amendments, ERC
activity increased. The contemporaneous emission reduction requirement was deleted and new
provisions were added to prevent excessive emissions in any single area from creating "hot
spots" of unhealthy air. The amendments established sensitive zones where increased emissions
were prohibited, and only allowed trades to downwind areas.
To assist small businesses, SCAQMD created a community bank of ERCs available to
firms that require offsets of less than two tons per year. These small air pollution sources may
39Marketable Permits Program Working Paper #1, South Coast Air Quality Management
District, May 1991, p. 1-4.
View Page Image


CRS-53
apply for no-cost credits held in the community bank. The bank is partially funded by emissions
reductions from old shutdowns that were never claimed. Although the bank's deposits are
currently sufficient to cover requests for credits from small businesses, it is possible that requests
could exceed deposits.
The Federal new source review program now requires all increases in emissions to be offset
by emissions decreases that are 20 percent greater than the corresponding increase (offset
requirements of 1.2:1). The 1990 amendments to the District regulations required that all holders
of ERCs return them to SCAQMD for a review of company emissions records. After the review,
the ERCs were reissued, but often devalued. For example, credits that were granted for
equipment shutdowns were reduced in value by 80 percent. However, the total number of credits
actually increased, because many firms did not know they were eligible to receive credits.
Credits representing almost 2,000 tons of air emissions have been traded since implementing the40

1990 amendments to the SCAQMD program.


As discussed later in the report, the increasing sanctions for noncompliance in the 1990
Clean Air Act Amendments and its comprehensive permit program appear to have increased the41
attractiveness of the emissions market to industry. Experience with the offset program, as
Dwyer observes, provides valuable insights for efforts to establish a more effective emissions
trading market in southern California. He notes that the efforts to mix command and control
regulations with emissions trading in the offset program reduced supply and demand, increased
transactions costs, and increased uncertainty about the security of the "property right" to
overcompliance.42
Other examples of attempts at regulatory efficiency gains through trading are presented
briefly in the summary discussion and tables below, based on an earlier report by Hahn and
Hester. 43
Direct Discharge Permit Trading
As described in Table 4, this trading system for paper mills and other dischargers in
Wisconsin has been effect since 1981. It initially appeared to hold promise for reducing waste
treatment costs of paper mills and municipal wastewater treatment plants for meeting river water
quality standards. However, control costs proved to be lower than expected and with one
exception, no trades have taken place.44 Restrictions on trading, the time required to get State
approval, and the uncertain tenure of the discharge rights apparently have all worked against
potential trades among companies.
40Personal communication, Tracy Goss, South Coast Air Quality Management District,
February 2, 1993.
41Dwyer, John P. Op. Cit. p. 112.
42Ibid.
43Hahn, Robert W. and Hester, Gordon L. Marketable Permits: Lessons for Theory and
Practice. Ecology Law Quarterly. Vol. 16, May 1989. pp. 361-406.
44Carlin, Alan. Op. Cit. p. 5-15.
View Page Image


CRS-54
Point-Nonpoint Sources Trading
Two states, Colorado and North Carolina, have established programs for reducing nutrient
discharges to water supply reservoirs in the one case and a river basin, in the other.
Colorado
In Colorado, two local governments in the Denver area have established programs for
accommodating future economic growth by allowing dischargers of phosphorus loadings with
high treatment costs to "buy" comparable or greater abatement from lower-cost sources, usually
diffuse nonpoint polluters.
Dillon Reservoir. This trading system for the Dillon Reservoir in Colorado is designed
to allow point sources credit for reduced phosphorus loadings by paying for reductions in
nonpoint sources. Table 5 describes the features of this program. Rising control costs to meet
strict discharge limits for point sources and substantially lower incremental control costs for
nonpoint sources is the rationale for this trading system. While only a few trades have taken
place to date, the structure of the trading options and cost differences between sources looks
promising for reducing future compliance costs.
Cherry Creek Reservoir. This system started in 1984 by Summit County uses a trading
ratio of 2 to 1 between point and nonpoint sources to provide a margin for new growth.45 As
noted by EPA, slowdown in regional growth and improved treatment efficiencies have decreased
the need for trades. Interestingly, some discussion of trades between nonpoint sources has
occurred which was not expected as part of the program.
The Tar-Pamlico River Nutrient Strategy (North Carolina)
The newest example of a trading system for water quality control purposes is being
undertaken in the Tar-Pamlico River basin of North Carolina. A nutrient management strategy
is being pursued in this region to address
accelerated eutrophication problems. The goal of the strategy is to implement the concept of
nutrient trading to accomplish an overall reduction in phosphorus and nitrogen by allowing
certain point source dischargers to contribute cost-sharing funds to reduce loadings from
agricultural runoff.
In September 1989 the North Carolina Environmental Management Commission classified
the Tar-Pamlico as a nutrient-sensitive water (NSW), based on assessments of low dissolved
oxygen levels, decreased aquatic
vegetation, loss of wetlands, and presence of algal blooms. The Commission subsequently
proposed a number of regulatory steps to improve water quality and recommended a nutrient
reduction goal of 206,000 kilograms per year from point sources discharging into the river basin.
To allow for anticipated increased flows to wastewater treatment plants in the basin by 1995,
meeting this reduction goal would have required those point sources to reduce nutrient discharges
below 1986 levels and incur significant capital and operating expenses in the process.
45Carlin, Op.Cit. p. 5-16.
View Page Image


CRS-55
Instead, a proposal was developed to allow facilities to achieve the original nutrient
reduction goal by substituting other, more cost-effective measures. In December 1989 the State,
the Environmental Defense Fund, and a local environmental group entered into a point-nonpoint
source trading agreement with a coalition of one private and 13 municipal dischargers, the Tar-
Pamlico Basin Association. Under the terms of the agreement, point source dischargers that are
members of the Association are jointly responsible for meeting a steadily decreasing total
nutrient limit over a five-year period, rather than having individual nutrient permit limits
enforced.
Association members may achieve this overall nutrient limit by reducing their own effluent
levels, by trading individual discharge levels among themselves, or by paying a fixed cost ($56
per kilogram) to a fund that implements nonpoint source controls through the State's agricultural
cost-share program. The fixed cost amount is based on the average nonpoint source control cost
in the Tar-Pamlico area and includes a safety factor of 3:1 for46
cropland control measures and 2:1 for confined animal operations. A safety factor is
incorporated at least until actual reductions from nonpoint source controls are better quantified.
The major responsibility for implementing the Strategy is assigned to the Association
through three broad requirements. It must:
Provide funding (approximately $400,000) for the development of a nutrient model
for the river to better define the relationship between nutrient loading and water
quality.
46Hall, John C., Ciannat M. Howett. The Tar-Pamlico Watershed: A Case Study in the Use
of Pollution Credits Trading to Reduce Point Source Control Costs and Enhance Non-Point
Source Regulation. Undated. 5 p.
View Page Image


CRS-56
TABLE 4. WATER POLLUTION PERMIT TRADING (FOX RIVER, WISCONSIN)
PURPOS E
To help achieve water quality standards for the Fox River, a waterway heavily used for waste disposal by
several dozen paper mills, where required abatement technology had not brought the river up to regional
quality goals
HIS T ORY
1972- Water Pollution Control Act authorized EPA to set standards for water quality, with States establishing
permit systems for individual discharges
1981- Wisconsin established a program to allow point sources of wastes which cause biological oxygen
demand on the Fox River to trade discharge rights
M E CHANIS M
State discharge permits which established the initial allocation of discharge rights set limits for the entire
plant, rather than individual sources within the plant
Trading is allowed only if the facility buying the rights is new, is expanding production, or cannot meet the
discharge limits in its permit even with use of the required abatement technology
Acquiring firm must demonstrate to the State that the additional discharge is needed
Traded rights must be effective for a minimum of one year and cannot be effective for more than the
remaining term of the sellers discharge permit which is five years
For trades to be approved, permits for both parties must be modified, which can take a minimum of 175 days.
When permits are renewed, there is no guarantee that discharge rights which were sold will be reassigned to
a permit holder
Trades for which the sole justification is cost savings are prohibited
RESULTS
Only one trade has taken place between a paper mill which shut down its treatment operation and traded the
discharge permit to a municipal wastewater treatment facility which then began taking the mill's waste water
While there has been some interest in trades between mills, no additional exchanges have occurred
CONDITIONS AFFECTING THE PROGRAM
Difference between life of traded permits (maximum of five years) and the normal life of capital investments
in treatment facilities reduces incentives for trading
Minimum of one year on trades also limits seasonal flexibility further reducing incentives for potential
exch an ges
Lengthy permit process further reduces the value of potential trades
View Page Image


CRS-57
TABLE 5. WATER POLLUTION RIGHTS TRADING (DILLION RESERVOIR, COLORADO)
PURPOS E:
To help reduce the cost of abatement and thus achieve greater reduction in phosphorus to the reservoir by
allowing point sources(e.g., municipal treatment plants) to trade discharges among themselves or also pay for
reduction of nonpoint sources
To allow the area to avoid treatment capacity constraints on local economic growth
HIS T ORY
Dillon Reservoir was becoming eutrophic (overenriched) in the early eighties due to discharges from sewage
treatment plants and from nonpoint sources (septic systems and urban runoff)
Even if point sources could be reduced to zero, phosphorus from nonpoint sources would still result in
eu trophication
The reservoir is both a major source of water supply for Denver and is also important to Summit County as
part of its recreation-based economy
In 1984, a coalition of governments and private interests adopted a plan requiring that advanced treatment
techniques be applied to point sources and that nonpoint sources new after 1984 be required to use controls
to minimize phosphorus waste loads
The plan included provisions which allow trading of rights to discharge phosphorus among various sources
Generally, cost of reductions for nonpoint sources are lower than for point sources (for example, the
incremental cost for removing one pound of phosphorus at a wastewater treatment plant in Summit County
is estimated to be $860 compared to $119 for nonpoint sources)
TRADING MECHANISMS
Point sources are allowed to acquire discharge rights in excess of the amounts allowed under the plan
Rights can be acquired from point sources or from nonpoint sources existing before 1984
Trading ratios are 1 to 1 for point sources and 2 to 1 for point sources acquiring rights from nonpoint sources
(to provide a margin of safety in light of uncertainty about nonpoint sources controls)
To implement the "trade" between point and nonpoint sources, point sources agree to pay for and install
phosphorus reductions at nonpoint sources, acquiring a property right by the credit they get for phosphorus
reduction
RESULTS
One trade to date involving a developer paying for sewering of some septic systems
Waste load allocations set in the 1984 plan have growth margins for point sources thought to be sufficient
through 1990, after which trading for reductions from nonpoint sources will be the only way to accommodate
future municipal waste loads
Cost savings are uncertain, but trading will allow continued economic growth
CONDITIONS AFFECTING THE PROGRAM
Few apparent restrictions on trading, though transaction costs are not yet known
A long term concern is proper maintenance of measures involved in trades, especially nonpoint source
contro ls
View Page Image


CRS-58
Provide funding ($13.3 million over five years) for implementation of agricultural
Best Management Practices (BMPs). This represents the amount needed to achieve
the entire nutrient reduction goal by three municipalities (Greenville, Pinetops, and
Rocky Mount) which are expected to expand prior to 1995.
Provide $150,000 to the State for the Division of Soil and Water Conservation to
administer implementation of the BMPs. The State will enter into contracts with
farmers to carry out designated BMPs.
In addition, dischargers in the Association were required to perform engineering
evaluations at their plants to determine operational or minor capital improvements that could
meet desired nutrient levels. Ironically, this initial step led the Association members to stay
below the State's nutrient limits every year since the agreement was signed by means of making
relatively inexpensive operational changes instead of additional capital investments. Thus,
because the point sources dischargers have been able to reduce their own pollution discharges47
at relatively low cost, they have not yet had a need to formally trade for nonpoint source credits.
However, as facility growth occurs, the need for trading is likely to become more important, and
funding has been contributed for the agricultural BMPs, in anticipation of that happening.
As an incentive for all point source dischargers to join the Association, the 1989 agreement
provides that if the Association fails to meet any of its requirements, then all existing dischargers
with design flows greater than 100,000 gallons per day will be required to meet stringent effluent
limitations.
In developing the program thus far, a number of issues have arisen, including State
resource constraints and the initial lack of information: the Association agreed to fund a nutrient
model for the river basin largely because none had previously existed and because the State
lacked expert resources to produce a model that would identify nonpoint sources, quantify their
impact, and determine the relative effectiveness of controls.48
Generic implementation issues faced in this case included how to establish the price for the
trading system (i.e., the trading ratio of nonpoint source controls that a point source discharger
must undertake in order to obtain a credit and the price of such a credit); overcoming the
reluctance in some to deviate from traditional command-and-control regulation, even though
trading offered the opportunity for a more cost-effective and environmentally appropriate
program; and ensuring enforceability of agricultural BMPs in contracts between the State and
farmers.
Even in its early stage and even though trades have not yet occurred, the Tar-Pamlico
agreement is believed to be working well as a means of achieving
water quality goals at lower total cost. Through an unusual partnership of State officials,
environmentalists, and municipal and industrial dischargers, a new approach to water quality
control has been developed. The agreement is expected to reduce nutrient pollution to the Tar-
47Ibid., p. 3.
48Personal communication, John C. Hall, Kirkland & Cody, April 27, 1993.
View Page Image


CRS-59
Pamlico watershed by the same amount as a traditional regulatory approach, but at an estimated
tens of millions of dollars in cost savings.49
MEETING NATIONAL POLLUTION REDUCTION OR PHASE-OUT
REQUIREMENTS THROUGH TRADING
The three programs in this category represent widely varying scope and implementation
experience.
The lead trading system was implemented within the refinery sector which
regularly trades product among companies. By most accounts, the program
facilitated the phase-out of lead in gasoline by easing the transition costs for smaller,
less technically advanced, refineries.
The sulfur dioxide allowance trading system potentially could involve hundreds
of utilities (on a mandatory basis) and other industrial facilities (on a voluntary basis)
in exchanges which may reduce the costs of a mandatory sharp reduction in sulfur
dioxide emissions by the year 2000. In contrast to the lead trading program, this
exchange mechanism will involve State regulatory bodies, the regulated utility sector,
other stationary sources, possibly financial institutions, as well as the Federal EPA.
Its complexity and long lead time allow only speculation as to whether it will meet
its initial cost-saving expectations and open market trading potentials.
The chlorofluorocarbon production allowance trading system is intended to
ease the phase-out of CFCs by allowing the half a dozen manufacturers to trade
decreasing quotas among themselves prior to final phase-out. To date, this system
has seen little if any use, in part because supply of CFCs has exceeded demand for
a variety of economic and regulatory reasons.
Lead Trading
Of the various examples of trading, EPA's program for phase-down in the lead content of
gasoline is generally considered a success in reducing the costs of environmental compliance.
As summarized in Table 6, the trading program worked because of previous industry experience
in trading products and additives, because of minimal administrative requirements for trading,
and because of the ability to "bank" (for future use or trading) lead reductions exceeding EPA
standards. Not only did trading lower the compliance costs to refiners, it resulted, according to
some analysts, in even greater savings to retail gasoline consumers, as it lowered the costs of
marginal suppliers in a highly concentrated industry, resulting in lower gasoline prices.
49Hall and Howett, Op. Cit., p. 5.
View Page Image


CRS-60
TABLE 6. EPA LEAD TRADING AND BANKING
PURPOS E
To facilitate the transition to a more stringent standard for lead in gasoline
To provide a degree of flexibility for those refiners, usually smaller ones, that might have technical difficulties
in meeting tighter standards
TRADING MECHANISM
Amount of leaded gasoline produced by the firm determined quantity of lead rights
Refiners adding less lead to gasoline than allowed by EPA allowed to trade lead rights equal in volume to the
difference between actual and permitted lead levels
Refiners desiring to add more lead than allowed required to buy rights from refiners adding less lead than the
EPA standards
HIS T ORY
1973/78Required reduction of average lead content starting in 1975 but delayed until 1978 because of
litigation
1974 -EPA required that unleaded gasoline be available to avoid poisoning catalytic converters
1978 -Lead designated as a criteria air pollutant under the Clean Air Act
1982 -Lowered limits slightly on gasoline lead content and allowed trading in "lead rights"
1985 -Further tightened standards and announced that banking would be allowed at the beginning of 1986
1985 -Allowed carryover or "banking" of lead rights between quarters retroactive to the beginning of
1985 (previously rights expired at the end of each quarter). Rights could be exercised in any
quarter through 1987.
RESPONSE
Market in lead rights was very active, increasing throughout the life of the program
Sharp increase beginning in 1986 reflected an extensive use of banked rights
Most large refiners and one-third of small refiners created and banked rights during 1985
Roughly equal proportions of small refiners bought and sold lead rights, suggesting that not all small refiners
had difficulty meeting the EPA standards
Large refiners used the program more extensively than small refiners, though small refiners did benefit both
by banking and by purchasing banked rights from large refiners
IMPACTS ON COSTS AND THE ENVIRONMENT
The percent of lead rights traded as a percent of all lead used increased from under 10% in 1983 to almost
60% by the end of 1987
Cost savings to refiners estimated by EPA prior to beginning of the program
of over $200 million based on forecast from a linear programming model assuming optimal behavior and
ignoring increased monitoring costs
No apparent adverse effect on the environment with the shifting of allowed lead use among refiners. On the
other hand, the number of violations of lead content went up
CONDITIONS AFFECTING THE PROGRAM
Introduction of banking seemed to stimulate trading
Limited restrictions and administrative requirements on trades including equal treatment of banked and
currently used rights
Heavy reliance on self monitoring and reporting by refineries
Already well established market in refinery feedstocks and products so that personnel used to trading with
each other already were in place
View Page Image


CRS-61
Sulfur Dioxide Allowance Trading
The new acid rain control program authorized by the 1990 Clean Air Act Amendments is
based on a comprehensive permit and emission allowance system. An allowance is a limited
authorization to emit a ton of SO2. Facilities receive allowances based on specific formulas
contained in the law. These allowances may be traded or banked for future use or sale.
Allowances sales and auctions are to be held to ensure liquidity in the allowance market. If an
affected unit does not have sufficient allowances to cover its SO2 emissions, it is subject to an
excess emission penalty of $2,000 per ton and must reduce an additional ton of pollutant the next
year for each ton of excess pollutant emitted. The law also contains special provisions
(additional allowances and/or extended deadlines) for phase 1 powerplants (under a 1995
deadline) that choose to install control technology achieving a 90% reduction of SO2 and for
powerplants choosing to repower with clean coal technology during Phase 2 which begins in the
year 2000.
EPA promulgated several of the important implementing regulations for the allowance
system in late 1992 and is currently facing various challenges in further promulgation of
regulations. These rules involve costs both to the participants and to the government (including
State and national entities). With the release of the Environmental Protection Agency's (EPA)50
regulatory impact statement (RIA) and the Internal Revenue Service (IRS) allowance guidance
document, the magnitude of these costs are becoming more clear. According to the RIA, the
implementing cost of Title IV could run between 15 and 25 percent of the total cost of the
program. Although the combined reduction/ implementation costs are substantially below the
cost of the reductions without any market-based or flexible implementation scheme, they are
significant.
The estimated costs of the acid rain control program annualized over the eighteen year
period 1993-2010 are presented in Table 7. Because the costs are annualized over eighteen
years, the estimates presented generally overstate the annual costs during the early years of the
program (Phase 1) and understate the costs in the out years. As indicated, the major
implementation costs for the control program are the transaction and tracking costs (particularly
if commission rates are higher than ICF assumed), and the monitoring costs.
The transactions costs could be particularly important in determining the numbers of trades
conducted. Several projections of transactions and savings were based on "knife-edge"
decisions--decisions which did not include either transactions costs or tax implications.51 If
either, or both, of these factors entail significant costs, trading activity could be retarded.
50ICF Incorporated. Regulatory Impact Analysis of the Proposed Acid Rain
Implementation Regulations. Prepared for Office of Atmospheric and Indoor Air Programs,
Acid Rain Division, U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. July 30, 1992.
51On tax implications of allowance holding and trading, see Internal Revenue Service. Rev.
Proc. 92-91. Internal Revenue Bulletin 1992-46, November 19, 1992.
View Page Image


CRS-62
Table 7. Implementation Costs by Cost Category
(Annualized costs, 1993-2010, 1990$)
Cost CategoryIncremental AnnualizedPercentage of Total
Cost (1993-2010, millionsAnnualized Cost of
of 1990 dollars)Program
SO2 Reduction Costs$700-$1,30076%-85%
Transaction and Tracking$14.8-$29.5* 2%
Costs
Auctions, Direct Sales, and$0.1-$0.6<.1%
IPP Guarantee Costs
Conservation/ Renewable$0.1<.1%
Fund Costs
Monitoring (CEM) Costs$203.5 22%-13%
Permits $3.5 <1%
Total $922-1,537100%
*This estimate assumes a commission rate of 1.5% on transactions. ICF also calculates a
6% commission rate scenario as an upper-bound case. In that case, the transaction and
tracking costs range to roughly $59-$118 million annually. This cost would raise
transaction and tracking costs to 6%-8% of total costs and reduce direct reductions costs
to 72%-80% of total costs.
Source: ICF Incorporated, p. ES-7.
In terms of tax treatment, the IRS has held that the costs of acquiring or holding an
allowance must be capitalized and that allowances may not be depreciated. In terms of cost
recovery on the sale or exchange of allowances, the utility will realize capital gains or losses on
the difference between the amount realized and the utility's adjusted basis in the allowance. This
tax situation will also figure into the calculus of any trading decision.
Two years after enactment of the acid rain control title, few trades have been announced.
The few that have are the result of bilateral negotiations with undisclosed prices as shown in
Table 8. If this continues, the program could go the path of EPA's bubble policy in producing
considerably less savings than expected, particularly in phase 1.52
52For the possibility that allowance trading may be sequential and bilateral (at least initially),
see Parker, Larry B., Poling, Robert D., and Moore, John L. Clean Air Act Allowance Trading.
21 Environmental Law, no. 4, 1991 (part II). pp. 2021-2068; for bilateral and sequential trading
being a problem with the bubbling policy, see Atkinson & Tietenberg, Market Failure in
Incentive-Based Regulation: The Case of Emission Trading, 21 Journal of Environmental
Economics and Management, 1991. p. 19
View Page Image


CRS-63
The development of an active market in allowances is more likely to occur in phase 2, since
new sources will have to find allowances from existing sources, and there should be an ample
supply of allowances from several overcontrol options such as low-sulfur coal, oil and gas,
utilization shifts, retrofit scrubbing, and sorbent injection. The components necessary for such
an effective trading system to emerge include a broad-based spot and futures market, and
brokering systems for longer term contracts that will likely be the bulk of allowance transactions.
One encouraging development is the decision by the Chicago Board of Trade in July 1991
to undertake allowance futures trading. To date, this proposal has not been implemented. The
Chicago Board of Trade also conducted EPA's first allowance auction in March of 1993. While
EPA sold all of the allowances it offered, few of the allowances offered by utilities were taken.
Observers suggest that utilities stayed out of the market because their needs are not pressing at
this time. Thus, early transactions in allowances have not yet revealed the potential for this
trading mechanism.
On the negative side, the first sulfur dioxide transaction, in which the Tennessee Valley
Authority (TVA) bought 10,000 allowances from Wisconsin Power and Light Company in July53
of 1992, has apparently run into significant local opposition. Local environmental groups
charged that TVA was buying the right to pollute. Reportedly, a TVA official suggested that this
type of local response may make cautious utilities even more reluctant to trade. Other factors
affecting early trading may be slow response by the Environmental Protection Agency and by
several State public utility commissions in finalizing
rules and cost recovery principles for trading. The tendency of some States to protect the local
coal industry also may be an important concern.54
53 Lobsenz, George. "Malec Pens Gloomy Assessment of SO2 Trading Opportunities."
The Energy Daily. Vol. 21, No. 133, July 14, 1993. p 1.
54 Ibid.
View Page Image


CRS-64
Table 8. Transactions in Sulfur Dioxide Allowances
BuyerSellerDateNo. of One-TonPrice Per Credit
Credits
Tennessee ValleyWisconsin PowerSpring 199210,000$250-$300
Authority& Light
Duquesne LightWisconsin PowerSpring 199215,000 (withAbout $300
& Light10,000 more
optional)
Ohio EdisonAlcoa GeneratingSummer 199225,000 (5,000 aAbout $300
year for 5 years)
Illinois PowerCentral IllinoisSpring 199380,000 (16,000 aAbout $200
Power Serviceyear for 5 years)
Illinois PowerPacific Corp.Spring 199350,000 (10,000 aAbout $200
year for 5 years)
Illinois PowerWisconsinSpring 1993750,000 (15,000 aAbout $200
Electric Poweryear for 5 years)
Source: Wall Street Journal. CBOT Plan for Pollution-Rights Market is Encountering Plenty of Competition,
by Jeffrey Taylor. August 24, 1993. P. C1
Chlorofluorocarbon Production Allowance Trading
In response to both domestic law (the Clean Air Act as amended) and international
agreement (The Montreal Protocol on Substances that Deplete the
Ozone Layer), the United States is well down the road toward complete phase-out by 1996 of
production of chlorofluorocarbons (CFCs) and other ozone depleting substances.55 For most
55 Chlorofluorocarbons (CFCs) have been indicted scientifically as responsible for an ongoing
depletion of the ozone content of the stratosphere. The indictment was handed down in 1973;
the societal response has come in stages. First, the United States and several other countries
banned the use of CFCs in aerosol products. This occurred in 1978 and led to an abrupt, though
temporary, drop in CFC usage around the world.
Secondly, through intensive international negotiations under the guiding hand of the United
Nations Environmental Program (UNEP), a series of international agreements has been
hammered out. In 1985, a Convention for the Protection of the Ozone Layer was agreed to by
20 countries. The Convention provided a mechanism for further negotiations. In 1987, 47
countries signed on to the Montreal Protocol on Substances that Deplete the Ozone Layer. Under
the terms of this Protocol, CFC production was to be capped at 1986 levels one year after it came
into force (which turned out to be Jan. 1, 1989), followed by a 20% cut over 3 years and an
(continued...)
View Page Image


CRS-65
uses, the phase-out will probably not cause severe economic impacts. For air conditioning and
refrigeration equipment, however, shortages of refrigerant in 1996 and thereafter could cause
sharp increases in refrigerant prices and shortages of equipment able to use the new generation
of refrigerants. Despite this possibility, there is no current program or even program plan to
cushion the transition.
To implement the requirements of the Montreal Protocol, EPA issued regulations in 1988
and a temporary final rule in 1991 governing production cuts. Title VI of the Clean Air Act
Amendments of 1990 provided for statutory recognition of the Protocol production phase-out.
In addition, the amendments called for a comprehensive set of regulatory requirements covering
recovery, recycling, and disposal of CFCs when equipment containing them is serviced or
discarded.
The EPA in 1991 established a phase-out system which includes tradeable production56
allowances. In implementing the system, EPA apportioned baseline allowances, established
a gradual reduction in allowances, and allowed the transfer of allowances among firms.
Production allowances that are transferred reduce the firm's production base proportionally plus
an additional one percent of the amount transferred.
To date, little activity has taken place under this trading system. Where there have been
exchanges, it is not clear from data available to EPA whether these are normal product exchanges
at the plant level between competitors or participation in the CFC production allowance trading
system.57 As designed, the trading system grandfathered production allowances to the half-
dozen producers but did not give other parties such as large consumers opportunity to bid for the
decreasing supply of CFCs. In designing the program, EPA considered an auction system but
rejected this broader mechanism for a variety of reasons including concerns about its legality.
Lack of activity in the trading program may also be the result of the imposition of tax on CFCs
as discussed below. In fact, the production allowance has never been fully used. In addition to
55(...continued)
additional 30% by 1999. Five CFCs and three halons (bromine-containing substances) were
listed.
In 1990, with over 70 countries now involved, the Protocol was strengthened to require a
100% phase-out by 2000 and by adding two chlorine-containing non-CFC solvents -- methyl
chloroform and carbon tetrachloride -- to the phase-out schedule. A phase-out schedule for a set
of first generation substitutes -- hydrochlorofluorocarbons (HCFCs) -- was also set, with an
ultimate target date of no later than 2040. In 1992, the Protocol was strengthened again. CFCs,
methyl chloroform, and carbon tetrachloride are to be phased out by the end of 1995, with an
interim goal of 75% by 1994. HCFCs are to be 90% phased out by 2015 and completely phased
out by 2030.
56 Carlin, Alan. Loc. Cit. p 5-7.
57Personal Communication, Willard Smith, Office of Policy Analysis, Air Policy Branch,
Environmental Protection Agency, Washington, D.C., July 15, 1993
View Page Image


CRS-66
the effect of the tax, a slower growing economy and rapid expansion of substitutes may have
contributed to a surplus of production over market needs.58
A further complicating factor in the allowance trading system would have been DuPont's
follow-through on its recent announcement that it would stop producing all CFCs a year ahead
of the required January 1, 1996 deadline. Since DuPont's production represents half of remaining
new supply, the early phase-out would have added to the difficult problem of maintaining the
existing stock of air conditioning and refrigerating equipment. After considerable agonizing and
internal debate, EPA asked DuPont to continue to produce its allowance in order to help generate
enough stocks to cushion the impact of the phase-out. Dupont agreed, with reluctance, to
produce whatever quantities up to its allowance, were ordered from it.
INTERNALIZING SOCIAL COSTS THROUGH
NONREGULATORY MEANS
Some indirect market-based approaches offer ways to lessen intrusive and costly
regulations while meeting environmental management objectives. In practice, however, such
techniques have been tried sparingly to date or applied for reasons other than environmental
protection.
CFC Tax
The tax on CFCs is the only current example of taxation of a pollutant at sufficient levels
to cause apparent change in behavior. While observers suggest that the tax has had an effect on
CFC phase-out pace, most see the tax more as a way to capture windfall revenue in a situation
of tightening supply.59
After a several-year-long debate on whether an auction system or a fee or tax would be
preferable, a tax was first placed on CFCs60 in 1990 (Omnibus Budget Reconciliation Act
[OBRA] of 1989), revised and extended in 1991 by the OBRA of 1990, and revised upward in
1993 by the Energy Policy Act of 1992. Starting in 1990, as a result, CFCs became subject to
both a production quota (decreasing over time) and a tax (increasing over time).
The mandated phased decreases in production volumes for products whose markets have
been growing at up to 10% per year has led to increased CFC prices. CFCs cost about 60 cents
per pound before the phasedown began; they now cost about $2 per pound prior to application
of tax. The tax began in 1990 at $1.37 per pound (multiplied by the ozone depleting factor
[ODF] which for CFC's is either 1.0 or close to it). It is now $3.35 per pound, scheduled to rise
58 For an overview discussion of the CFC phase-out see: Congressional Research Service.
U.S. Library of Congress. Stratospheric Ozone Depletion: Regulatory Issues. CRS Issue
Brief IB89021, by David E. Gushee. Updated regularly.
59Ibid.
60 For simplicity's sake, the term "CFC" will be used hereafter in this section to encompass
all Class I controlled substances, including halons, methyl chloroform, and carbon tetrachloride,
unless noted otherwise.
View Page Image


CRS-67
to $4.35 per pound in 1994 and $5.35 per pound in 1995. Purchase prices about tripled in 1990
and are currently up to about 10 times their pre-regulation prices.61
By the end of 1991, CFC production was down to 60% of 1986 levels; by the end of 1992,
it was down to under 50% of 1986 levels. Looking back on this history from the vantage point
of 1993, this rapid a phasedown of production is remarkable given the perception in 1987 that
the best that could be done was 50% by 1999. Clearly, both government and industry have been
aggressive in forcing change in a number of CFC-dependent industrial sectors which thought,
until the ozone depletion concern arose, that they had found and were using cheap, safe, high-
performance products.
The role of the CFC tax in causing this major change to happen appears to have been more
important in some industrial sectors than others. Its impact has been greatest where the CFC cost
is itself the major cost factor, with decreasing impact where capital cost of the CFC-using
equipment or of the manufacturing facilities where CFC-using equipment is produced is large.
Other factors are cost and availability of effective substitutes, cost of design changes needed to
convert to the substitutes when the needed design changes are known, and the cost, complexity,
and development time when the knowledge needed for design changes must be developed.
For example, when CFCs cost 60 cents per pound, most substitute foam-blowing agents
were more costly. The rising costs of CFCs has made these substitutes competitive. Processing
equipment changes needed are relatively minor. In some electronics and other cleaning
operations, water-based solvents can be made effective enough at costs below those of CFCs,
methyl chloroform, or carbon tetrachloride including the tax. There appears to be little doubt that
the tax has accelerated the adoption of substitutes in many of these applications and is a positive
factor in looking forward to the likelihood that the production phaseout by 1996 will not cause
major sectoral dislocations.
Where CFC-using equipment is being serviced, the combination of impending regulations,
technician training programs, and increasing CFC cost has led to rapid penetration of CFC-
capturing equipment. Examples are auto and building air conditioning service operations. CFCs
are still used, but eventually perhaps half to two thirds of the volumes needed will be generated
through recovery, reclaiming, and recycling. The tax has provided a cost basis for the creation
of some reclaiming operations sooner than would the price rises through production phasedown
alone. However, the regulatory program is the primary driving force, as evidenced by the rising
cost of service. Not only are the make-up refrigerants more expensive but the recovery
equipment must also be paid for.
Where CFC-using equipment is being produced (refrigerators and air conditioners, for
example), producers are required to redesign the equipment and develop new lubricants to be
compatible with the substitute refrigerants. The process of developing the refrigerants and
testing out the design changes is critical in these applications; the tax is not as important as the
CFC production phaseout schedule in accelerating the development schedule. Another delaying
factor here, however, is the pressure against HCFCs, whose limited future life-spans limit their
entry into some equipment lines, while other substitutes' futures are clouded by, among other
considerations, uncertainties in the EPA process of granting approval. It is not certain that, for
61Taxes in some applications are not applied in full. Rigid foam applications are an example.
View Page Image


CRS-68
refrigerators and room air conditioners in particular, there will be a smooth transition to
alternatives when the phaseout deadline passes.
Where CFC-using equipment is currently in use, the CFC price (including tax) is not high
enough to force retrofit to non-CFC products following any individual need for a service call.
There appears to be minimal impact from the tax. Examples are chillers in grocery stores,
building air conditioners, auto air conditioners, and refrigerators. In these uses, the CFC price
would have to be a great deal higher than it now is to force economics-based decisions to retrofit.
A more critical driving force in favor of retrofit is the cost of finding slow leaks and the growing
unwillingness of service companies to "top off" rather than find the leak.
Some companies with multiple pieces of equipment and on replacement schedules as part
of their preventive maintenance (PM) programs are replacing CFC-using equipment when its
scheduled life has expired with non-CFC-using equipment (currently mostly using HCFC-22)
and banking the salvaged CFCs. This is not tax-driven, however, but "prudence-driven", since
the PM schedules have long time horizons which incorporate post-phaseout years when supplies
of CFCs needed for servicing may well not be available at any price.
Private citizens, commercial building operators, and small businesses, however, do not
appear to be thinking in such long time frames. For them, the current CFC price, even though
perhaps 10 times as high as it was five years ago, is not high enough in itself or as a signal of
things to come, to cause action. The tendency of these groups to resist retrofit today in favor of
the hope that there will be no penalty tomorrow is causing some observers to predict a state of
near-chaos in late 1995 and the first several years after the phasedown is complete. The tax on
CFCs would have to be significantly higher today than it is to affect this posture, according to
those actively involved in trying to accelerate retrofit. A higher tax, on the other hand, might
lead to increases in prices for substitutes and thus an economic drag rather than an increase in
driving force for retrofit.
In sum, the CFC tax has clearly accelerated the rate at which CFC uses are being substituted for
and the rate at which CFCs are being recovered for reuse. The tax has also achieved one other
purpose. It has increased U.S. Treasury revenues. Cumulative Treasury revenue from the tax
is currently estimated to be about $4.6 billion.
Permit Fees
Most States use permit fees to partially or completely fund their environmental regulation
and management programs. Dealing with air pollution, for example, the California South Coast
Air Quality Management District charges annual permit fees for stationary sources ranging from62
a few dollars per ton for carbon monoxide to over $200 per ton for volatile organic compounds.
While several hundred dollars per ton may have some disincentive effect for some sources,
incremental abatement costs for that region are several thousand dollars per ton for major
pollutants. Thus fees in this case serve to finance regulatory programs, as they do in many other
States, and do not serve as abatement incentives per se.
62 South Coast Air Quality Management District. Form C: Summary of Emissions and
Determination of Fees for Plant Premises for Calendar Year 1987. Los Angeles, California.
View Page Image


CRS-69
Permit fees are generally considered a means of enabling regulatory agencies (generally
States) to obtain a stable, predictable source of revenues to support permitting, planning, standard
setting, enforcement and other environmental program responsibilities. Permit fee systems vary
widely, but they tend more to represent "fee for service" mechanisms than market-based
measures to internalize the societal costs of pollution or to supplement traditional regulatory
systems.
At the State level, fee systems are an important source of revenue to supplement or replace
Federal funds and to cover program administration costs not supported by general revenues. In
the area of State solid waste management, 21 States use permit fees, but many assess fees only
to cover the cost of administering the permit program or the costs of engineering review for a
permit application. Differences in scale and scope are reflected by two States. Colorado uses
permit fees to fund a minimal program involving review of permit applications and inspections,
while New Jersey has a wide-ranging program of permit, product, and other special fees that
includes regulation of medical waste, closure of landfills, litter control, recycling permits, and63
others.
More than 30 States use fees to finance water quality activities, with almost 80 percent of
the revenues coming from water permit fees, water rights applications, and training and64
certification fees for water management personnel. While many States impose lump sum
charges or flat fees for permit applications and review, a number of them charge for discharge
permits based on volume, toxicity, or other characteristics of wastes discharged. California's
wastewater fee schedule, for example, is a sliding scale based on the type of waste and the
volume. New York States's pollutant discharge fee system is split into
private/commercial/industrial, industrial, and municipal, with each having a separate fee schedule
based on a facility's average daily discharge.65
At the Federal level, there is recent and growing interest in enacting permit fee
requirements to ensure that States will have available the funding needed to administer Federal
environmental laws. In 1990 amendments to the Clean Air Act (P.L. 101-549), Congress
directed States to establish comprehensive permit programs and to collect fees sufficient to cover
the direct and indirect costs of administering the new program.
Building on that enactment, legislation in the 103rd Congress (S. 1114) would impose a
similar permit fee requirement for water quality management programs. The Clean Water Act
already has a comprehensive permit program as a fundamental tool of compliance and
enforcement. The pending legislation would require States to collect permit fees from industrial
and municipal point sources in amounts adequate to recover 60 percent of the costs of
administering the point source elements of a State's water quality programs, including permit
63 New York State Department of Environmental Conservation, Division of Solid Waste.
Survey of State Funding for Solid Waste Management Programs. June 1991. p. 5.
64 Shields, Evelyn. Funding Environmental Programs: An Examination of Alternatives.
National Governors' Association. 1989. p. 22-24.
65 Anderson, Robert C., Lisa A. Hofmann, Michael Rusin. The Use of Economic Incentive
Mechanisms in Environmental Management. The American Petroleum Institute, Research
Paper #051. 1990. pp. 37-38.
View Page Image


CRS-70
review, enforcement, water quality monitoring, preparing regulations, and developing and
administering sewage sludge disposal and pretreatment programs.
Input Fees
Some State and Federal agencies use fees on potentially damaging substances as part of
program administration. These fees are not for the purpose of incentives, though they offer the
beginnings of that type of policy. Two examples are the feedstock taxes used in the Superfund
and a variety of agricultural fees as part of nonpoint source water pollution control programs.
Superfund Feedstock Tax
The Comprehensive Environmental Response, Compensation, and Liability Act of 1980
(CERCLA), as amended in 1986, provided for several taxes to support the program. A feedstock
tax on 42 different petrochemicals, at a rate between $0.22 per ton and $4.87 per ton, is one of
three taxes. Tax rate differences between feedstocks were based on estimates of the amounts of
hazardous wastes generated from each specific feedstock. The law also provided for a tax on all66
domestic and imported crude oil and a corporate environmental tax.
The main purpose of these taxes is to help finance a portion of the Superfund program.
However, the tax rates are not sufficiently high to have any measurable incentive effect on either
the production or disposition of hazardous wastes.67 Thus, as with most other Federal and State
taxes or fees in the environmental area, the tax helps to spread the cost of the current Superfund
program broadly without affecting the decisions that lead to the generation and disposal of
hazardous wastes.
Agricultural Nonpoint Source Control
Agricultural sources of nonpoint source water pollution are now widely recognized as a
major--if not the major--problem in abating pollution of both surface waters and groundwaters.
Attention is focused on several pollutants, particularly sediments, nutrients, and pesticides.
Long-standing programs are in place to conserve soil, which reduces not only sediment loss to
surface waters, but also phosphates and those pesticides which tend to adsorb on soil particles.
More recently, primary concern has turned to those pollutants which are soluble in water and
which may be transported to contaminate groundwater--particularly nitrates and various
pesticides, including alachlor, aldicarb, DBCP, and atrazine. A nationwide EPA survey of
groundwater contamination by pesticides and nitrates indicates that a small proportion of
66 U.S. Library of Congress. Congressional Research Service. Summaries of Laws
Administered by the Environmental Protection Agency. Report No. 93-53 ENR. Washington,

1993.


67 Carlson, J. Lon and Bausell, Charles W. Financing Superfund: An Evaluation of
Alternative Tax Mechanisms. Natural Resources Journal. Winter, 1987. p. 117
View Page Image


CRS-71
drinking water wells exceed health standards.68 But within these national averages are some
much higher rates of contamination in local areas.69
Developing methods for controlling agricultural sources of nonpoint source pollution has
proved elusive, however. For several reasons, established regulatory approaches that have been
more or less successful in controlling point sources of water pollution do not translate easily to
this area of concern: sources are numerous compared to most categories of point sources; site-
specific variables mean that a practice in one field may cause water pollution while the same
practice in an adjacent field does not; the pollutants are not wastes so much as unutilized inputs
intentionally dispersed into the environment; the agricultural sector's relationship to government
and the economy differs from industry's, and so on. The special circumstances of agricultural
nonpoint source pollution and the problematic effectiveness of controlling it through regulation
have directed attention to alternative approaches for controlling this problem: these alternatives
include government encouragement of ``Best Management Practices'' (BMPs), an approach
analogous to soil conservation programs; land use controls, normally at the local level; and
economic incentives and disincentives.
Economic Incentives and Disincentives. Several concepts of using economic incentives
and disincentives in programs to abate agricultural sources of nonpoint source pollution have
emerged:
in the traditional economic sense, using taxes or fees to internalize the costs of
pollution to the users of fertilizers and pesticides;
using taxes or fees to generate funds to support research and development on more
efficient, less-polluting use of fertilizers and pesticides, to share the cost of farmers'
adoption of such practices, and/or to compensate farmers for restrictions on pesticide
or fertilize use or on land use; and
making various governmental benefits, such as price supports, contingent on a
farmer's complying with particular management practices or pollution control
requirements.
Internalizing Nonpoint Source Pollution Costs through Pollution Taxes. The idea of
taxing agrichemicals with the intent of reducing use to avoid external costs has received
theoretical attention, but little practical application. For theoreticians, a key problem has been
68 Environmental Protection Agency. National Survey of Pesticides in Drinking Water
Wells, EPA 570/9-90-015. 1990.
69 For example, an Iowa survey documents extensive contamination of shallow aquifers by
nitrate. Approximately 18 percent of Iowa's private, rural drinking water wells contain nitrate
concentrations above the recommended health advisory level, and and in certain southern and
western areas of the State, where dependence on shallow wells is high (deeper aquifers are
naturally saline), over 30 percent of the wells exceed the standard. Burton C. Kross, et al. ``The
Nitrate Contamination of Private Well Water in Iowa,'' American Journal of Public Health.
Vol. 83, no. 2. February, 1993. pp. 270-272. Similarly, localized instances of pesticides in
groundwater have led to local bans or restrictions on pesticide use (e.g., aldicarb use is prohibited
on Long Island).
View Page Image


CRS-72
evaluating the external costs of agrichemical use, a necessary step in assessing costs and benefits
in order to determine an appropriate level of taxation.70 But many practical problems have also
intervened. Aside from political considerations,71 objections to using taxes or fees at levels
necessary to reduce agrichemical pollution include (1) that higher fertilizer and pesticides costs
would hurt farmers already using them efficiently; (2) that there would not be any necessary
geographic correlation between reductions in their use and pollution problems; and (3) that the
demand for fertilizers (and probably pesticides) is quite inelastic (one estimate suggests that a
100% tax on fertilizer would be required to reduce fertilizer use 40%72). A British study came
to similar conclusions--that ``high levels of taxation (two to three times the original price level)
are necessary to induce large cutbacks in [nitrogen] fertilizer use and that accompanying
reductions in farm income would be very large--up to 50%.'' The authors of the British study
concluded that ``a tax or levy on fertilizers is unlikely to have a major influence on nitrate
leaching [and] ... such a tax applied to the UK alone could damage the country's competitive73
position.''
A recent article compared five basic options, including taxes, for controlling nitrogen74
fertilizer use to protect groundwater. Table 9 summarizes the pros and cons of the alternatives
and indicates that taxes rate high on cost and
enforcement, but low in responsiveness to local problems and political viability. Variations
designed to improve the targeting and effectiveness of agrichemical taxes have been proposed:
for example, a graduated fertilizer tax might be effective since high application rates would
normally pose the greatest risks to groundwater, or rebates could be paid to farmers who employ
BMPs; such variations have yet to receive much formal analysis. Whether more attention to
economic incentives/disincentives, combined with government revenue needs, might make
agrichemical taxes more politically viable remains problematic.
Agrichemical Use Fees. While proposals to tax agrichemicals at levels designed to reduce
their use remain largely academic, some modest fees have been imposed on fertilizers and
pesticides in order to raise revenues to support agrichemical-related governmental activities.
70 Smith, V. Kerry. Environmental Costing for Agriculture: Will It Be Standard Fare in
the Farm Bill for 2000? Resources for the Future. Discussion Paper QE92-22. (August 1992).
71 The political context in which controlling agriculture nonpoint source pollution occurs is
discussed in David R. Lighthall and Rebecca S. Roberts. ``Agricultural Chemicals and
Groundwater Quality: The Political Economy of Policy Responses.'' The Environmental
Professional. Vol. 10, no. 3. 1988. pp. 211-222. See also D.D. Francis. ``Control Mechanisms
to Reduce Fertilizer Nitrogen Movement into Groundwater.", J. of Soil and Water
Conservation. Nov.-Dec. 1992. pp. 444-448.
72 Fleming, Malcolm H. ``Agricultural Chemicals in Groundwater: Preventing Contamination
by Removing Barriers against Low-Input Farm Management.'' American Journal of Alternative
Agriculture. Vol. I, no. 3. p. 129.
73 Department of the Environment. Nitrate in Water. Pollution Paper No. 26. Her Majesty's
Stationery Office. London, 1986. pp. 59-60.
74 D.D. Francis.
View Page Image


CRS-73
Potential uses of such fees include financing regulatory activities, such as registration or setting
of tolerances for pesticides; supporting research into alternative production technologies,
supplementing farm income supports, and providing financial incentives to catalyze the transition
of Midwestern agriculture to a more diversified and profitable system;75 funding an "insurance
program" to protect farmers from diminished yields as they fine-tune use of fertilizers and
pesticides and paying for research and extension services;76 ``subsidiz[ing] provision of drinking
water supplies on farms and in rural towns'';77 and subsidizing water treatment.78
As of January, 1993, 46 States impose some kind of fee on fertilizers.79 The fees vary, but
typically are less than $1.00 per ton (in 1991 the farm price for nitrogen was in the $150-200 per
ton range); in 4 States fees ranged from $1.00 to $3.10 per ton. Over 30 States dedicated all or
part of these revenues to inspection, 9 to unspecified research, 7 to `general fund,' 4 to
groundwater, 2 to cleanup, 1 to `State water plan,' and 1 to alternative agriculture programs.
TABLE 9. RELATIVE COMPARISON OF FIVE BASIC OPTIONS FOR CONTROLLING N FERTILIZER USE
ptionsCost*EnforcementResponsivenessPoliticalProducerEquity Among
to Local ProblemsViabilityIncomeProducers
se TaxLowEasyLowLowReduceHigh
ts to purchaseModerateDifficultLowLowReduceHigh
ations restrictionsHighDifficultVariableHighMaintainLow
or Reduce
RegulationsHighDifficultHighHighReduceLow
ntary BMPsLowNA**VariableHighMaintainHigh
ative cost to implement, administer, and enforce.
t applicable unless governmental agencies restrict timing of BMPs etc.
75 Lighthall and Roberts, p. 219.
76 Nipp, Terry. ``Water Quality and Agricultural Production Issues and Research Needs.''
Memorandum to Charles Benbrook, Executive Director, Board on Agriculture. August 8, 1988.
p. 3.
77 Caulfield, Henry P. Jr. ``The Federal Environmental Legislative Process.'' in V. Novotny,
ed., Nonpoint Pollution: 1988 - Policy, Economy, Management, and Appropriate
Technology. American Water Resources Association. 1988.
78 Department of the Environment. Nitrate in Water. p. 60.
79 Data compiled by The Fertilizer Institute.
View Page Image


CRS-74
Iowa illustrates the use of such levies. The State's 1987 Groundwater Protection Act
creates a Groundwater Protection Fund, supported by a series of fees, which include a nitrogen
fertilizer tax of $0.75 per ton, based on an 82%-Nitrogen solution. These receipts are deposited
in an Agricultural Management Account of the Fund. The Act specifies that these funds shall
be used to "develop nonregulatory programs to implement integrated farm management of farm
chemicals for environmental protection, energy conservation, and farm profitability; interactive
public and farmer education; and applied studies on best appropriate technology for chemical use
efficiency and reduction." The original form of the legislation would also have imposed a 1%
tax on pesticides sales as a revenue source for research. In the end, the legislation increased the
registration fee for pesticides and dealer licensing fees, with the revenues going also to the
Agricultural Management Account. It has been suggested that the resistance to the tax reflected
a fear that it would place Iowa's farmers at a competitive disadvantage, implying that this policy
should be considered at the national level.80
In late 1993 an expert panel examining opportunities to manage farming systems so as to
protect soil and water recommended research directed at the design of market-based incentives81
to protect soil and water quality. More specifically, observing that increased funding would
be needed to support initiatives to comprehensively address soil and water problems, the report
urged exploration of ``taxes on agricultural chemicals, fuel, heavy tractors, moldboard plows,
irrigation water, and other inputs that can be related to soil and water quality degradation from82
agricultural production practices....'' ``Relatively low taxes on nutrient and pesticide inputs''
would substantially augment current programs, says the report: ``One percent ($128 million) of
the annual 1990 expenditures of $12.8 billion on pesticides and fertilizers, for example, is more
than 65 percent of the total 1992 expenditures on cost-sharing under the Agricultural
Conservation Program, and more than 18 times the total 1992 expenditures on the Water Quality
Incentive Program.''83
Federal Agricultural Support Programs. The level and distribution of use of
agrichemicals is strongly influenced by national agricultural policies and programs.84 For
example, price support programs can discourage multi-year crop rotations that would diminish
the use of pesticides, because of requirements to maintain base acreages in supported crops like
corn that require intensive agrichemical use; and, by keeping support prices high on such crops
as corn, higher rates of fertilizer use become economic than at lower crop prices.
The initial steps to reconcile goals occurred in the 1985 Farm Bill. It included provisions
for "compliance," which make certain subsidies contingent on farmers not cultivating wetlands
or highly erodible lands. In effect, these provisions make farmers' subsidies contingent on
80 Lighthall and Roberts, pp. 216-217.
81 Committee on Long-Range Soil and Water Conservation, Board on Agriculture, National
Research Council. Soil and Water Quality: An Agenda for Agriculture. Washington, D.C.
National Academy Press, 1993. p. 16.
82 Ibid., p. 142.
83 Ibid.
84 See Fleming, and Lighthall and Roberts.
View Page Image


CRS-75
farmers' adopting environmentally desirable practices. Provisions in the 1990 Farm Bill
reaffirmed the general structure and direction of compliance, while adding a number of new
programs that could provide related environmental benefits, especially improved water quality.
Current compliance requirements do not specify practices designed to protect groundwater,
but some are suggesting movement in that direction and new conservation planning requirements
could strongly reinforce this movement. Another option, which may be discussed in future farm
bill debates, is removing (or reducing) price supports, which would tend to remove (or diminish)
one
incentive for farmers to maintain high agrichemical use.85 The concept behind this and related
proposals would be to change agricultural economics in ways that encourage farmers' to choose--
in response to price signals or income expectations--management practices for agrichemicals that
are more efficient and result in less intensive agrichemical use. However, if subsidies are
reduced, incentives to be in compliance will also decline, suggesting the need of alternative86
tools.
Wetlands Mitigation Banking
Wetlands provide significant benefits to society in the form of fish and wildlife habitat,
water quality protection, and water flow regulation. However, the Nation continues to lose
wetlands at an estimated rate of 290,000 acres per year. While a portion of these losses results
from natural forces, the largest share results from man's activities.
Protection of wetlands from development impacts has been implemented through regulation
at the Federal and State levels. Compensatory mitigation has been required of developers whose
projects cause unavoidable adverse impacts. Developers have complained about both the costs
associated with compensatory mitigation and about costly delays resulting from regulatory and
permit programs. Wetlands mitigation banking is a relatively new natural resource management
concept which provides for the advanced compensation of unavoidable wetland losses due to
developmental activities through more cost-efficient and potentially more publicly beneficial
means.
Mitigation banks are established by formal agreement between jurisdictional resource
agencies and a mitigation bank sponsor, generally a private landowner or public agency. The
sponsor creates, restores, or enhances wetlands or wetland functions and in return receives credits
for the habitat enhancement or other public benefits which are determined to result from that
work. These credits may be drawn upon (hence, debiting the account) in order to fulfill wetland
mitigation requirements for development impacts at other locations, generally within the same
hydrologic unit or habitat area. The credits may be used by the sponsor or sold to other permit
applicants. In general, banks fit into two categories: dedicated banks, whose principal objectives
85 Fleming, pp. 128-129.
86 It has been observed that in the U.S., given current cropping and agrichemical use patterns,
about 40% of the revenues of any general agrichemical tax would be paid by corn farmers--
leading one analyst to conclude, ``Since the Corn Belt suffers from widespread ground water
contamination, and since corn farmers also receive a large portion of government support
payments, a tax on agrichemicals may help solve several problems at once'' [Fleming, p. 129.].
View Page Image


CRS-76
are compensation of wetland losses associated with discrete types of construction activity and
which generally are sponsored by single construction entities; and commercial banks, which are
established by private entrepreneurs and whose wetland credits are available for purchase on the
open market.
By mid-1992, an inventory of banks identified 37 banks in active operation and another 64
in various stages of planning, and reported that the number of active banks had more than tripled
in four years' time.87 Approximately two-thirds were located in coastal areas where both
development pressures and wetlands losses have recently been significant. Of the active banks,
19 were sponsored by State highway departments (to mitigate wetland losses due to highway
construction), eight involved port development (with commercial port authorities serving as
sponsors), seven involved general land development, a total of three involved agricultural
drainage, mining operations, and oil and gas activity. In addition, five active mitigation trusts
were identified. In the latter cases, developers make cash contributions to a trust fund maintained
by a local, State, or Federal entity in order to cover the wetland losses for which they are
responsible. Accumulated monies are used to provide replacement wetland areas for after-the-
fact mitigation purposes.
Owing to the relative newness of the concept, little information concerning the performance
record of banks is available. Permittees and bank sponsors generally give them high marks
because of the degree of efficiency and predictability they bring to the permit review process.
Others, including some Federal and State resource agencies and conservation groups, contend
that wetlands restoration and creation efforts have not been uniformly successful, thus calling
into serious question the basis for providing credits from the bank. These and other
implementation issues suggest that while mitigation banks appear to be a promising tool for cost-
effective wetlands protection, successful implementation requires thorough understanding of the
ecosystems in question and some degree of resource agency guidance on methods of determining
credits and debits.
Information Requirements
Several examples illustrate the use of mandatory disclosure of information as a way to
create possible incentives for nonregulatory reductions in hazardous substances.
SARA Section 313
One national example of the use of information intended to improve public knowledge and
ultimately private management of harmful substances is Section 313 of Title III of the Superfund
Amendments and Reauthorization Act. Title III requires manufacturers and users of toxic
chemicals to provide a wide array of information to the public concerning the amounts of such
chemicals stored on-site and released to the environment. Under Section 313, manufacturing
establishments handling any of 329 listed substances must report annually the amount of the
substances released to air, water, or land. The information is compiled by EPA into a toxic
release inventory. The data are also available through an EPA computer system that allows users
to identify emissions for specific companies as well as to aggregate releases by chemical and/or
by geographical area. EPA recently proposed adding several more substances to this list.
87 Reppert, Richard. Institute for Water Resources, U.S. Army Corps of Engineers. Wetlands
Mitigation Banking Concepts. IWR Report 92-WMB-1, July 1992. 25 p.
View Page Image


CRS-77
Release of data from the first inventory, in April 1989, showed that over 20 billion pounds
of the chemicals were released or disposed of in 1987 by the 17,500 facilities that reported. The
availability of the data is widely expected to increase pressure on industries and individual
facilities to reduce emissions. In fact, EPA announced in May 1993 that 1991 industrial releases
of toxic chemicals had dropped by 30 percent since the "baseline" year of 1988.88
Proposition 65
The passage by direct voter initiative of the California Safe Drinking Water and Toxic
Enforcement Act (Proposition 65) is a good example of using information along with regulation
as a way to help reduce an individual's exposure to potentially harmful substances.
Proposition 65 provided for several mechanisms that reinforce market forces for reducing89,90
exposure. First, for a list of chemicals known to cause cancer or reproductive toxicity,
businesses must explicitly warn people if the business is knowingly not keeping exposure below
a defined minimum-risk level. Businesses may exceed the level, but they must tell the public
they are doing this and give the chemical dose. This provision provides two incentives. One to
consumers to examine what it is they are buying compared to another product. The second to
businesses to participate actively in the rapid definition of what the minimum-risk level for the
chemical should be. This latter incentive is in direct contrast to current regulatory systems where
those regulated have incentive to fight definition of safe levels as long as possible. In the
California case, businesses want to be able to market their products against competitors. They
therefore have every incentive to have the minimum-risk level determined quickly and to stay
below it in order to avoid the warning label. This reversal of the burden of proof has powerful
effects. Instead of regulators having to prove that a manufacturer is above the line of safety, now
the manufacturer has to prove that it is below the safe level.
Second, for the same list of chemicals, businesses are prohibited from discharging any of
them to drinking water. While this is a regulatory mandate, the law does not require proof that
a drinking water source has been irretrievably damaged or that somebody has developed cancer
as a result of discharges. The provision shifts regulation to prevention before contamination can
occur.
Three, enforcement of the provisions is increased by allowing citizen and public defender
suits with plaintiffs receiving a percentage share of any fines that are levied for violations. This
provides strong incentives for producers to self-police their operations rather than waiting for
regulatory enforcement under more traditional systems.
88U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. Environmental News. Washington, D.C. May 25,

1993.


89 Roe, David. An Incentive-Conscious Approach to Toxic Chemical Controls. Economic
Development Quarterly. August 1989.
90 Also see: Roe, David. Barking up the Right Tree: Recent Progress in Focusing the
Toxics Issue. Columbia Journal of Environmental Law. Vol. 13, No. 2. 1988.
View Page Image


CRS-78
New Jersey's Environmental Cleanup Responsibility Act
Another example of the shifting of burden of proof through mandatory information
disclosure is New Jersey's 1983 Environmental Cleanup Responsibility Act (ECRA). This law
requires that industrial establishments dealing with hazardous wastes submit a "negative
declaration" or a hazardous substances cleanup plan to the New Jersey Department of
Environmental Protection as a precondition for the closure, transfer, or sale of the property.
Failure of the seller to meet the requirements of the Act is grounds for voiding the sale, and the
buyer can recover damages from the seller in such cases.
In the period since passage of ECRA, the law has had significant effects on the real estate
and banking industries as well as the industrial operations that generate hazardous waste.
Extensive literature on the problems include uncertainties over coverage, disagreement over what91
triggers ECRA, and the time the regulatory and approval process takes.
Although this State act remains controversial, one of its main effects has been to shift the
initial cost and burden of proof for environmental audits from the buyer to the seller. Thus an
incentive has been created for industrial facilities to eliminate improper practices in the disposal
of hazardous wastes in order to ease future sale or transfer of assets.
Liability Assignment
Toxics
Implementation of both Superfund and the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act relies
in part upon a financial responsibility requirement under which disposers of hazardous chemicals
have to demonstrate that they can handle the costs of corrective action. Treatment, storage, and
disposal facilities must also show financial responsibility for proper closure and post-closure care
regardless of contamination. Though both acts encourage insurance to cover the cost of pollution
damage, large companies that can demonstrate financial capability may self-insure. Insuring
these type of risks has proved difficult because of the uniqueness of such events and because of
the unpredictability of court decisions on damage awards. Insurance companies also have not
been in a position to raise rates sufficiently to cover the uncertainty since large companies have
the option of self-insuring, thus raising further the costs of those still buying.
Groundwater
Liability assignment also has become an issue in groundwater contamination by pesticides.
Connecticut's 1982 Potable Drinking Water law follows the principle of strict liability for
groundwater contamination, and requires a responsible party to provide potable drinking water
to replace contaminated water. This provision was invoked against five of the State's largest
farms, following contamination of groundwater by a pesticide, Ethylene Dibromide (EDB). The
farmers appealed orders to provide potable water and fines. The case was settled in August 1988.
Most fines were dropped and the State legislature enacted a bill specifying that farmers using
pesticides for agricultural purposes, strictly adhering to label requirements, having a plan to
91 See for example Schmidt, Joseph W. Jr. New Jersey's Experience Implementing the
Environmental Cleanup Responsibility Act. Rutgers Law Review. Vol. 38. 1986.
View Page Image


CRS-79
minimize contamination, and keeping complete records could not be compelled to provide
alternative water. However, the strict liability requirement was continued for damages.
The question of farmer liability for pesticide use has also become an issue in reauthorizing
and amending the Federal Insecticide, Fungicide, and Rodenticide Act.
Deposit-Refund for Managing Solid and Hazardous Waste
Federal programs for solid and hazardous waste management were authorized in the
Resource Conservation and Recovery Act of 1976 (RCRA) and in subsequent amendments.
Under these laws, regulation and enforcement have focused on the 6,000 treatment, storage, and
disposal facilities for hazardous waste. While substantial progress has been made as a result of
this program, other aspects of solid waste disposal (e.g., industrial nonhazardous waste facilities)
have been neglected. Even in the hazardous waste program, it has become clear that there are
limits to what can be accomplished by focusing on the disposal end of the process. At some
point, attention needs to be placed on the waste generators.
But here one immediately encounters a practical difficulty: the number of actors whose
behavior one seeks to change is extremely large. Hazardous waste is generated by approximately

650,000 entities, including gas stations, dry cleaners, schools, photo developing labs, and others,


and small amounts of hazardous waste in products such as paint, batteries, pesticides, and
cleaning solvents are generated by nearly 100 million entities, including households, office
buildings, commercial establishments, and institutions.
There is no conceivable enforcement mechanism that can address the large number of entities
generating solid and hazardous waste. Thus, some attention continues to be focused on
approaches that provide incentives to reduce waste generation or to manage wastes in more
acceptable ways, such as deposit-refund systems.
In addition to beverage containers, deposits and refunds have been applied to auto batteries
and to pesticide containers (in Maine).92
Beverage Containers
Most new proposals for deposit-refund systems are based on the experience of ten States
with regard to beverage container deposits. States with refund systems for beverage containers
(generally referred to as "bottle bills") report that 72-97% of deposit containers are returned for
recycling, even though consumers are not required to return the containers. The economic
incentive (a 5 or 10-cent refund per container) is sufficient to produce the desired behavior.
Comparable data are not available for mandatory recycling programs (those not using deposits93
and refunds), but anecdotal evidence suggests that they are far less successful.
92 Project 88, Harnessing Market Forces to Protect Our Environment. pp. 130-131.
93 "Where Recycling Is Spoken, Fines Add Some Clarity," New York Times, March 21,
1989, p. B1. The article reported on experience with mandatory recycling in Jersey City, New
Jersey. About 20 percent of Jersey City residents actually comply with the mandatory program,
according to the city's recycling director. See also McCarthy, James E. Bottle Bills and
(continued...)
View Page Image


CRS-80
Lead Acid Batteries
Deposits on lead acid motor vehicle batteries have already been implemented by at least
ten States as a way to reduce problems with improper disposal.94 In the State programs, retailers
are required either to accept a used battery when selling a new one or to collect a deposit from
the customer. Some have proposed a national system that would include deposits at both the
manufacturing and retail stages with redemption centers for consumers to reclaim their deposits.
Redemption centers would reclaim deposits from manufacturers to close the financial loop.95
One possible issue in a deposit-refund program is the unintended incentive the deposit may
have for theft. Some speculate that too large a deposit may make it worth while to steal batteries
for redemption. This could be countered by requiring proof of purchase, but such record keeping
raises the inconvenience level thus reducing the incentive to return batteries. Along similar lines,
inconvenience in the availability and proximity of return points for used batteries would limit
program effectiveness, unless the deposit were sufficiently high. In the above proposal, unless
the redemption centers were coordinated and linked to the existing auto-parts retail system, it
would seem that consumer inconvenience could work against program effectiveness. Actual
experience suggests, however, that these problems can largely be solved. A ten dollar return
value is only for buying a replacement battery, so there is no incentive to steal. Retailers take
the old batteries in trade solving the convenience problem.
Pesticide Containers
Since 1985, Maine has required deposits on limited and restricted use pesticide containers.
Under this State system, any restricted use pesticide container sold in the State must have a
sticker indicating that a deposit has been paid to the dealer. When a triple rinsed container is
returned, the deposit is refunded. As of 1990, over 13,000 containers had been returned. Given
deposits of up to $10.00 per container, this program appears to create a strong incentive effect.
93(...continued)
Curbside Recycling: Are they Compatible? U.S. Library of Congress. Congressional Research
Service. 93-114 ENR. January 1993.
94 Carlin, Alan. Loc. Cit. p. 4-1
95 Stavins, p. 63
View Page Image


CRS-81
PROPOSALS FOR NEW APPROACHES
Congress is currently considering a variety of market-type mechanisms in various
reauthorizations such as the Clean Water and Solid Waste Acts. Proponents for U.S. action on
mitigating possible global warming also are calling for taxes or tradeable overcontrol as means
for slowing carbon dioxide buildup. Market-based mechanism are also under consideration in
some State water resource management efforts as well as other Federal programs. While most
of the proposed mechanisms are not new in concept, many would break new institutional ground,
raising important questions about implementation.
ACHIEVING REGIONAL/LOCAL REGULATORY EFFICIENCY
Marketable Permit Programs In The Los Angeles Area
California's South Coast Air Quality Management District (SCAQMD) has been a leader
in developing and implementing innovative regulatory strategies often including economic
incentives. Since 1976, the District has been operating an emissions trading system for offsetting
new, modified, or relocated sources of air pollution as part of the new source review program.
SCAQMD recently adopted regulations to implement an emissions trading program as a means
of achieving further emission reductions from stationary sources.
Background
In October 1990, SCAQMD began development of a new marketable permits program called
the Regional Clean Air Incentives Market (RECLAIM). After three years of debate, public
hearings, and rule revisions, the RECLAIM program was adopted in October 1993. The rules
governing the RECLAIM program became effective January 1, 1994.
The program will require stationary air pollution sources to meet a specified reduction in
current emissions levels. Any reductions beyond the required level will result in the generation
of marketable credits. The marketable permits program is intended to help the South Coast air
basin meet its air quality goals while allowing industry flexibility in accomplishing reductions,
reducing compliance costs, and stimulating technological pollution control innovations. The
RECLAIM program requires the same overall emissions reductions that the traditional command-
and-control approach could achieve through the State Air Quality Management Plan (AQMP).
Air pollution sources can meet required reductions through the method of their choice, including
purchasing traded emissions, installing pollution control equipment, or changing production
processes or products to prevent pollution.
The emissions trading program will apply to 390 facilities that are major sources of nitrogen
oxides (NOx) emissions. In addition, 41 of these facilities will make up a second market for
sulfur oxides (SOx) emissions. Although there are currently 24,000 permitted facilities in the
District, the number of participants in RECLAIM is limited to 390 by excluding sources emitting
less than 4 tons per year of NOx or SOx. The District's initial proposal also included a market for
emissions of reactive organic compounds (ROC). The proposal to include ROC
View Page Image


CRS-82
in the RECLAIM program was opposed by business and industry leaders. After the program was
approved in October 1993, SCAQMD staff began new efforts to expand the RECLAIM program
to include ROC emissions.
The initial emissions allocation for all facilities is determined based on historical actual
emissions data including peak years of facility use. After determining baseline emission rates,
the program requires annual emission reductions. SCAQMD is expecting an 8.3 percent annual
reduction in NOx emissions and a 6.8 percent annual reduction in SOx. emissions by 2010 when
the RECLAIM program ends. Each facility will be issued a facility-wide permit detailing all
emission sources at the facility, establishing emissions limits, and specifying annual reduction
rates. Credits will be issued on an annual basis to facilities for each pound of NOx or SOx
emissions below the level required for that year. Credit trading will be allowed without any prior
approval from SCAQMD, as long as trades comply with certain geographical and seasonal
constraints. Increased compliance monitoring will be required to ensure that emissions
reductions are being achieved and that trades are being made properly.
The success of the RECLAIM program depends on meeting emissions reduction targets in the
District. Backstop provisions are necessary to ensure that the program achieves the necessary
reduction goals and that there is no backsliding. The RECLAIM program provides that facilities
exceeding their annual emissions allocation will be required to make additional compensating
reductions during the following year. Monetary penalties may also be applied to facilities
exceeding their emissions cap.
Implementation Issues
Although emissions credit trading programs receive considerable attention in the literature
regarding market-based environmental incentives, most of the discussion is theoretical. There
has been limited experience in the United States actually implementing trading programs on the
scale of the RECLAIM program. The acid rain allowance trading program under Title IV of the
Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990 should provide implementation experience to draw on,
however, few trades have been completed thus far. As the RECLAIM program becomes
operational, there are several issues regarding its implementation that should be considered.
Compliance and Enforcement.. Increased compliance flexibility for the regulated
community translates into an added enforcement burden for SCAQMD. To ensure the success
of the RECLAIM program, SCAQMD must be able to verify that the regulated community is
meeting its required emissions limits or purchasing the required number of credits. SCAQMD
must also confirm that credits have been properly generated and traded.
SCAQMD initially proposed using sophisticated emissions monitoring equipment to assist
in properly enforcing the program. For example, continuous emissions monitoring systems
(CEMS) would have been used to calculate emissions of NOx and SOx. CEMs automatically
record emissions data. The data would have been electronically transmitted directly to a central
District computer system that would examine the data to determine facility compliance
with emissions limits and reduction rates. Although daily monitoring might be appropriate and
cost-effective for large facilities, alternative monitoring methods were developed for smaller
facilities. The monitoring requirements are now correlated with the levels of emissions at a
facility.
View Page Image


CRS-83
To ensure that individual facilities meet their emissions caps, SCAQMD is relying on
backstop provisions in addition to stringent monitoring. Penalties for exceeding an emissions
cap will be linked to the price of RECLAIM trading credits. This removes any incentive to
violate the emissions cap rather than purchase credits.
To ensure that the basin as a whole is meeting its air quality goals, SCAQMD will institute
an automated tracking system. Reports will show actual emissions on a quarterly basis and will
allow the generation of geographical emission reports. The system will also track credit trades
so that SCAQMD can determine whether facilities hold the necessary number of credits for
compliance.
Compliance and enforcement issues will become more complex if ROC emissions are added
to the RECLAIM program. ROC is emitted from a variety of sources and products including
paints, coatings, adhesives, solvents, dyes, and inks. ROC sources also include combustion
sources such as boilers, heaters, internal combustion engines, kilns, furnaces, ovens, and dryers.
The ROC emissions from the use of a product cannot be calculated unless the product label
clearly certifies the ROC content. If all products containing ROC were properly labeled, each
source would still have to monitor the amount of each ROC-containing product used, and the
effectiveness of any ROC control equipment used in conjunction with the product.
SCAQMD initially proposed that all products be labeled with bar codes that indicate the
product's ROC content. Each time the product is used, the bar code would be scanned and ROC
content information would be electronically recorded. Companies would keep daily logs of ROC
usage. ROC emissions would be reported to the District on at least a monthly basis (more often
for large sources). The District considered an automated tracking system similar to the type of
accounting system credit card companies use. Each source would be issued a District 'credit
card" to be used for information reporting. Total emissions would be tracked electronically in
the same way credit card companies track total spending balances after each purchase is
recorded.
The District must ensure that the method of reporting emissions is adequate and that accurate
information is provided in a timely manner. If compliance determinations cannot be made
quickly, the District risks being unable to identify improper "edits before they are traded and used
by another company to demonstrate compliance.
Administrative Costs and Transaction Costs. Adequate enforcement will be one of the keys
to RECLAIM's success, however, it must be balanced with administrative costs. Although the
use of CEMs and automated ROG tracking would help ensure compliance, they would also
impose significant costs on RECLAIM participants. It may be difficult for RECLAIM to meet
both its program goals of reducing compliance costs below compliance costs of traditional
regulation) and reducing emissions to a level below that achieved through command-and-control
regulation. Administrative costs would need to be minimized so that they do not discourage
eligible facilities from participating in the market.
One of the largest administrative costs for the District could be the added personnel necessary
for additional compliance and enforcement activities. There is also an administrative cost
associated with recording trades and verifying that proper transactions have occurred.
In addition to the District's cost of administering the program, participants will incur private
transaction costs associated with trading. Transaction costs will result from the need to locate
View Page Image


CRS-84
trading partners. The District had developed a computer bulletin board that is available to the
public for the-purpose of listing offers to buy or sell credits. In addition, two firms have
announced their intention to hold a private auction of RECLAIM credits which they hope will
jump-start the credit trading market. The auction sponsors will use a computer system to match
buyers and sellers, and to identify market clearing prices. These measures should help limit
transaction costs.
Impacts
The consequences of the RECLAIM program may be evaluated not only in terms of air
quality improvements, but on the socioeconomic impacts as well. Some are concerned that
facility shutdowns will increase under RECLAIM adding to job loss in California and damaging
the State's economy. Some businesses may have additional incentive to move away from the Los
Angeles area because of potential profits from the sale of emission credits earned by shutting
down plants. To ensure retention of businesses in the area, the District is allowing shutdown
credits to be generated only by the 390 facilities in the RECLAIM market. Non-RECLAIM
facilities will not receive credits for shutdowns.
MEETING POLLUTION REDUCTION OR PHASE-OUT
REQUIREMENTS THROUGH TRADING
Tradeable Permits For Carbon Dioxide Control
Approaches to implementing a CO2 control program include: (1) regulatory schemes
involving efficiency standards and other mandated requirements, along with financial incentives
or subsidies; (2) consumption taxes (carbon, Btu or gasoline) on the various sources of CO2; and,
(3) emission reduction programs based on market incentives such as trading and banking of CO2
credits.96 These approaches are not mutually exclusive, but can be used in tandem to
complement each other. The following discusses trading and banking.
Background
The Clean Air Act Amendments of 1990 establish allowance-trading programs to control97
SO2 emissions and to phase out chlorofluorocarbons (CFCs), which deplete stratospheric ozone
(and also are greenhouse gases). The two programs differ in that the SO2 program provides for
trading of emission allowances while the CFC program provides for the trading of production
allowances of the ozone-depleting chemicals. Thus, the CFC program creates a market for the
right to produce certain quantities of the controlled substances rather than for the right to emit
96 Much current debate concerns the potential extent and timing of climate change; many
argue that controls are premature pending further scientific research and development. As noted,
this paper does not evaluate the extent or magnitude of the problem, but rather focuses on options
for addressing it. Research and development, and public education campaigns, while not directly
controlling emissions, will inevitably be essential components of developing and implementing
any policies directed at controlling climate change.
97 Sec. 607, Title IV, P.L. 101-549.
View Page Image


CRS-85
specified quantities of the substance. Paralleling the SO2 control program, most proposals for
CO2 control focus on the actual pollutant as the basis of trading, not the production rights.
In the emission trading approach,98 potential emitters of a pollutant are provided permits
or allowances for a specified activity--the production of a hazardous product, or an emission of
a pollutant--with each permit "worth" a unit of production or pollution (e.g., a ton of CO2). Each
affected facilities would be granted annual pollution permits corresponding to its allowed level
of emissions as set by legislation or regulation. No emissions above the level for which a facility
held permits would be permitted. However, facilities could choose to reduce their emissions
below permitted levels and sell the resulting excess permits received from those pollution
reductions to others. Facilities would be encouraged to trade these permits among themselves
or with others in order to find less costly ways of meeting the overall reduction in emissions.
By over controlling and selling excess permits, facilities with economies of scale or
generally low control costs can reduce their total costs of compliance. Those facilities that have
incremental control costs that are less than the price at which they could sell permits have an
incentive to overcontrol. Proceeds from selling the excess permits mean that the facility's total
cost of overcontrol could be less than if it just controlled to the mandated level. Ideally, the
excess allowances will be sold to utilities with incremental control costs above the allowances
price. By purchasing allowances for their emissions in excess of the standard, these facilities can
meet any requirement more cheaply than if they controlled to the required level. The desired
outcome is a lower total national cost for meeting the limitation than if all sources just met the
standards regardless of their differences in incremental costs.
If the market works efficiently, pollution reductions will be achieved cost-effectively.
Current experience with the SO2-allowance market is as yet insufficient to give much guidance
on how well a CO2 permit market might work.
Implementation Issues
The major economic advantage for a tradeable permit program is the flexibility that the
system would provide to emitters in complying with reduction goals. In controlling greenhouse
gases, this flexibility could include options beyond reducing emissions, such as increasing CO2
sinks (by planting forests for example), or permitting tradeoffs with controls on other greenhouse
gases, like methane. For example, a utility could choose to capture and burn coal-bed or landfill
methane, which would have the effect of offsetting its emissions of CO2. Hence, the program
could provide a broad range of alternatives to emitters in complying with the goals of the
program. Like a tax system, the trading system would encourage development of cost-effective
control measures as trading would provide flexibility to emitters in determining what specific
control to use in meeting mandated targets.
A further characteristic of this approach is that by focusing on the quantity side of the price-
quantity equation, it effectively limits total emissions--a characteristic that made it useful in
addressing acid deposition, and that makes it attractive for greenhouse gases. The option of
simply paying the price of pollution (as in a tax) is subject to prohibitively stiff penalties. Thus,
98 For example, see Daniel J. Dudek, "A Short Discussion of Greenhouse Gas Trading."
Prepared for the Keystone Global Warming Dialogue Policy Evaluation Working Group, August

1990.


View Page Image


CRS-86
the quantity of reductions achieved is much more certain than under a tax scheme. This would
provide some assurance to interested parties that a specific amount of CO2 would be reduced or
a specific trend in emissions obtained. For those confident that achieving a specific level of CO2
reductions will yield very significant benefits--enough so that even the potentially very high end
of the marginal cost curve does not bother them--then a regulatory system or tradeable permit
program may appear most appropriate.99 CO2 emissions would be reduced to a specific level,
and, in the case of a tradeable permit program, the costs involved would be handled efficiently,
but not controlled at a specific cost level.
Also, the program could be phased-in over time, beginning with a new source offset
program and later expanding to existing sources if necessary.100 Thus, the program could begin
with a offset provision requiring new sources to get permits from existing sources in order to
operate, and expanded over time to increase reduction targets on existing sources. However,
there is also the possibility that a ceiling on emissions could become a floor as no direct
economic incentive would exist to reduce emissions below the mandated ceiling.
Impacts
Implementing even the most elementary of this type of program raises several practical
issues. First, the more sources involved, the more complex and burdensome a trading scheme
becomes. A trading system would need the most sophisticated monitoring system of the
approaches outlined here. Besides determining a basis for the initial allocation of credits,
monitoring systems would be needed for determining compliance and for overseeing trades. For
small, diffuse sources, this could be a challenge. For example, 12% of all CO2 emissions comes
from the residential/commercial sector (space heating/cooling, water heating and appliances) and
33% from the transportation sources (trucks, automobiles, airplanes, etc.). Designing a tradeable
permit program to cover these sources (45% of total) would be a challenge. If an international
scope is desired, the monitoring question is multiplied again.
Second, when utilities are the sources affected, the trading scheme may pose unresolved
issues concerning the jurisdiction of State public utility commissions. Questions arise about how
investments in pollution equipment verses investments in permits might be treated. Such
questions are currently being asked with respect to the SO2 program with no consistent answer
yet.
Third, the initial allocation of permits/allowances/credits poses critical equity issues. One
option is to simply auction off initial allocations, which could adversely affect economically
disadvantaged participants. Another option is to distribute them free, which requires the
development of some allocation formula, for example according to existing emissions or
production. Yet another option is to allocate them according to a complementary regulatory
scheme. This initial allocation could be very complicated, depending in part on the numbers of
emitters and gases included in the program. Indeed, it may be more critical than under a tax
99 For a general discussion of emission permits versus carbon taxes in the face of uncertainty,
see Oates, Wallace E., and Paul R. Portney, Economic Incentives for Controlling Greenhouse
Gases. Resources for the Future. Resources, Spring 1991. pp. 13-16.
100 Daniel J. Dudek and LeBlanc, Alice, "Offsetting New CO2 Emissions: A Rational First
Greenhouse Policy Step," Contemporary Policy Issues, vol. 8, no. 29 (July 1990).
View Page Image


CRS-87
scheme as the permit program will generate no revenue to government for potential redistribution
to heavily affected areas or industries.
Liquidity of the trading system could require Government intervention in terms of auctions
or as a source of last resort. The necessity and degree of such intervention could affect the
efficiency of the system.
In summary, the development of a system where current and/or future CO2 emissions
allowances or permits (or credits) could be traded would introduce some of the advantages of an
economic incentive program while retaining some of the certainty of a regulatory system.
Likewise, implementation of a tradeable permit program would be easier than many regulatory
programs, but more difficult than a tax scheme, as is discussed later.
Recycling Credits in the Solid Waste Area
Solid and hazardous waste programs offer a clear example of the three factors stimulating a
reconsideration of market-based approaches. First, the United States is in the midst of a new
round of regulatory efforts that could increase dramatically the cost of traditional approaches to
waste management. As costs increase, the need to consider more efficient waste management
mechanisms grows.
Second, existing regulatory programs appear ill-conceived to manage many of the new
regulatory targets, such as gas stations, dry cleaners, households, and other small quantity waste
generators, whose numbers make traditional enforcement approaches impracticable.
Third, because of the Federal budget deficit, it appears unlikely that there will be increased
funding for existing or new control programs. Spending for solid and hazardous waste programs
grew more rapidly than other components of EPA's budget in the 1980s, but there are still
substantial backlogs of permitting and enforcement cases, and little attention is being given to
some potentially major problems. Thus, market-based approaches have drawn interest for their
ability to serve as revenue sources.
Background
During the 102nd Congress, more than 100 bills were introduced to revise and reauthorize
the primary Federal solid and hazardous waste law, the Solid Waste Disposal Act (SWDA).101
Many similar bills have been reintroduced in the 103rd Congress. These bills contain numerous
examples of economic incentives for solid waste management. They mostly create incentives
for reducing the amount of waste placed in landfills, collecting recyclable materials, reusing
recovered materials in manufacturing new products, or purchasing products that contain recycled
materials. Many of the sponsors of these bills believe that recycling is better for the environment
than landfilling waste because recycling may preserve natural resources and conserve limited
landfill space. Some believe that landfills are unsafe because they have the potential to leak and
contaminate nearby ground water. Although communities and private waste disposal companies
101 The Solid Waste Disposal Act (SWDA) is frequently referred to as the Resource
Conservation and Recovery Act (RCRA), the law which substantially amended the SWDA in

1976.


View Page Image


CRS-88
can continue to construct new landfill capacity, it is costly to meet Federal and State
requirements for new landfills and politically difficult to site new landfills.
There are more than 5,000 curbside recycling programs currently in place nationwide, up
from about 1,000 in 1988. The dramatic increase in collection has lead to an over-supply of
recyclable materials. Without a corresponding increase in the demand for collected recyclables,
municipalities and other recyclers have had difficulty identifying markets for the reuse of the
recyclable materials collected. Many of the proposed incentive approaches aim to jump start the
markets for collected recyclable materials by equalizing supply and demand. Bills introduced
in Congress attempt to stimulate demand where broad-based recycling markets have not thrived
(e.g., scrap tires, used oil, newspapers, etc.).
A series of bills aimed at improving markets for used lead-acid batteries, scrap tires, and
old newspapers was introduced in the 103rd Congress. The bills impose requirements on
producers and importers of these products requiring them to recycle an amount of their product
proportional to the amount of that product they produce or import. The recycling percentage
would be determined by EPA. EPA would also create a recycling credit system under which
recyclers could receive credits for recycling and producers or importers could purchase recycling
credits to comply with the recycling percentage requirement. The number of credits received
depends on the method by which recovered materials are managed. One method of reuse or
recycling could receive more credit than another to create a greater incentive for using one
recycling method over another. For example, a tire producer or importer could comply with the
recycling requirement by incorporating used tire rubber in the new tire manufacturing process,
retreading old tires, or purchasing recycling credits. Incorporating old tires into asphalt pavement
or retreading old tire casings generates twice as many credits as burning a whole tire, and four
times as many credits as shredding a tire for disposal.
The bills covering lead-acid batteries and old newspaper contain a slight variation on the
credit system for scrap tires. Rather than setting an overall recycling rate as proposed for scrap
tires, the bills set a minimum recycled content for new lead-acid batteries and newsprint. For
example, a producer or importer of lead-acid batteries could comply with the recycling
requirement only by recycling old lead in the production of new batteries, or by producing new
batteries with reclaimed lead purchased from a secondary lead smelter. The third compliance
option would be to purchase recycling credits from another lead-acid battery producer who
exceeded the minimum content requirement.
The main difference is that the minimum content approach encourages recycling of old
newspaper back into newsprint with recycled content and the use of lead from old lead-acid
batteries for producing new lead-acid batteries. This approach does not encourage the use of
recovered materials for anything other than the original product. It would discourage alternative
uses such as exporting recovered newspapers for recycling abroad.
Implementation Issues
The main assumption fundamental to the various bills is that existing markets for batteries,
newspaper, and tires are either non-existent or imperfect. Therefore, requiring those responsible
for producing or importing these goods to also recycle them enhances and stabilizes existing
markets, or creates markets that do not currently exist. One drawback is that in areas where these
markets do indeed exist and are working, these bills could interfere with the existing market by
imposing an artificial market. Recycling activity would center around the federally specified
View Page Image


CRS-89
recycling percentage or minimum recycled content and natural market forces that could
otherwise increase recycling above that level could be suppressed.
In some of these industries, where consumer behavior is an important part of the recycling
system, the effectiveness of these bills may be limited. For example, in the used battery
recycling industry, many manufacturers are already using 100 percent recycled lead in producing
new batteries. However, even if all manufacturers used 100 percent recycled lead, many used
batteries would not enter the used battery collection system. Various proposals encourage
increased collection by mandating that retailers accept used batteries. However, because the
behavior of individual consumers is so important to the collection of batteries, such proposals
may not be highly effective unless collectors provide incentives to consumers for returning used
batteries.
Whether a credit trading market will work, depends on the ease of identifying potential
market participants. For items covered by these bills, the number of recyclers is fairly limited,
therefore the number of credit generators would also be small. Nonetheless, brokers may be
needed to facilitate trades. Administrative costs could be very high if a credit trading market did
not develop on its own and EPA had to promote trading.
Transaction costs also need to be low. High transaction costs would limit trading because
it might raise the cost of purchasing credits close to the cost of compliance with the recycling
requirement or minimum recycled content requirement. The more information EPA makes
available on who has credits and who may need to purchase credits, the lower transaction costs
will be. Producers and importers must also be fairly certain that credits will be available and that
they will be available at a lower price than it would cost to meet recycling requirements on their
own. Long-term contracts would help reduce uncertainty of credit price and availability.
A credit trading system would be difficult to enforce because EPA would need to be able
to verify the number of credits a recycling firm generates, as well as whether the producer or
importer has purchased the proper number of credits. EPA could accomplish this through
inspections and audits of company records.
Impacts
All domestic producers and importers of any of the products covered by these mechanisms
would be affected by the legislation. Major consumers such as automobile manufacturers and
newspaper publishers would also be affected by the legislation. The cost of producing or
importing the covered products would rise because of the additional costs of purchasing
recycling credits or meeting the required recycling percentages. This could cause some
consumer price increases, depending on how large a component of total product cost the recycled
material was. Collectors of recyclable materials would see increased demand for these
commodities and possibly increased prices paid for them, depending on supply and demand
balances. Recyclers would also benefit by selling recycling credits to producers and importers.
These proposals could provide benefits to some industries while damaging others. Which
industries would be affected would depend on manufacturers' choices for recycling methods. For
example, if manufacturers find that it is cheaper and easier to recycle all used tires by making
them available to the rubberized asphalt industry, the tire retreading industry might suffer
because its access to retreadable tires would be diminished. Alternatively, if manufacturers
provided most of their scrap tires to tire burning plants, both the retreading industry and the
View Page Image


CRS-90
asphalt rubber industry would be harmed. This problem could be diminished by properly
weighing credits given for each use.
By providing an incentive for the use of batteries with recycled content, secondary lead
smelters could gain from the implementation of this bill, while virgin lead manufacturers would
suffer. The virgin newsprint industry would also lose market share to recycled newsprint
manufacturers, although the trend for newsprint as well as most other manufacturers is to
incorporate recycled materials into their operations.
These types of proposals could have an impact on existing State and local programs. Many
States already require the management of used batteries, tires, and newspapers. For example,
almost three quarters of the States have scrap tire laws or regulations or are considering such
legislation. Some State and local governments may have already entered into contracts with
private recycling operations that require the community to supply a specified amount of
recovered materials. For example, some local governments have contracts with rubberized
asphalt firms for the building of highways using scrap tires that require the local government to
provide a specified amount of used tires. If manufacturers must recycle tires on their own, the
number of tires available at municipal solid waste facilities may decline and become insufficient
to support rubberized asphalt road construction projects.
INTERNALIZING SOCIAL COSTS THROUGH NONREGULATORY
MEANS
Carbon Taxes102
Background
In the view of many economists, a carbon tax would be the most efficient approach to
controlling CO2 emissions. A pollution tax attempts to maximize net social welfare from
polluting activities. Economists observe that pollution imposes costs on society that are not
incorporated in the price of the goods or services responsible for the pollution; these are called
"external" costs. An ideal pollution tax "internalizes" these external costs by making the
beneficiary of the polluting activity pay a price that accounts for the socially borne costs. When
the tax is set at the level at which the marginal costs of more controls would just equal the
marginal benefits society gains by further reductions, society's net welfare is maximized.
Polluters, finding it cost-effective to reduce their emissions to avoid paying the tax, would add
pollution controls, or take other actions, to the point where further controls would cost more than
the tax or than the benefits society would gain. In the case of global warming, the pollutants
being taxed and the level of the tax would be based on their respective contributions to global
climate change and on an assessment of the future damages from climate change.
Implementation Issues
In practice, attaining a "socially optimal" level of control from an carbon tax may not be
achievable. Setting the tax at the level that maximizes net social welfare would require
102 Although this section focuses on carbon taxes, much of the discussion is relevant to other
tax proposals.
View Page Image


CRS-91
calculating external costs (such as of global warming). This is extremely difficult if not
intractable, because of uncertainties about effects, the problem of monetizing impacts, and other
scientific and methodological problems.103 For example, Cline has estimated the annual damage
from a doubling of CO2 equivalent from $61 billion (1990 dollars) to as high as $117 billion or
possibly more.104 Others suggest the damage could be lower than this range.105
Because of this uncertainty, a second approach to setting the carbon tax has been suggested
where a policy decision is made to achieve a stabilization or reduction in CO2 by a certain year
(for example, stabilization of emissions at their 1990 levels by the year 2000), and then to
estimate the tax level necessary to achieve that objective. Economic theory indicates that a
pollution tax is an efficient vehicle to minimize control costs for a given level of reductions
(regardless of whether the level achieves the ideal net social welfare). In this sense, a pollution
tax is efficient because it decreases the compliance costs of individual firms by allowing them
the flexibility to make the best use of information and technology relevant to their circumstances.
Individual firms can determine whether it is in their interest to pay the tax or to invest in
emission-abating alternatives. Since the tax must be paid on remaining emissions, firms have
a continuing incentive to innovate and find cheaper ways of reducing emissions.
However the tax is set, it creates an incentive to reduce emissions by raising the cost of
polluting. Hence, the purpose of the tax would not be to raise revenue per se (although it would)
but to induce reductions at the lowest costs achievable. Presumably, the policy goal would be
to set a carbon tax at a level to achieve a specific level of CO2 emissions by a specific date--given
the assumptions and uncertainties of predicting how a particular tax level would affect activities
emitting CO2.
Impacts
Besides being economically efficient, a carbon tax provides some protection against the
uncertainty of carbon reduction costs at the cost of some uncertainty about the quantity of
pollution reduced. Proposed CO2 reduction mechanisms present large uncertainties in terms of
the perceived reductions needed and the potential costs of achieving those reductions. In a sense,
preference for a carbon tax or another system depends to some degree on how one views the risks
and uncertainty regarding the necessity of achieving specific reduction levels versus the risks and
uncertainty regarding costs. If one is more uncertain about the benefits of a specific level of
reduction--particularly with the potential downside risk of substantial control costs to the
economy--then a carbon tax may appear most appropriate. In this approach, the level of the tax
effectively caps the marginal control costs that affected activities would have to pay under the
reduction scheme, but the precise level of CO2 reduction achieved is less certain--subject to the
boundaries and uncertainties of model projections. Basically a carbon tax resolves the "price
103 See Blodgett, John. Health Benefits of Air Pollution Control: A Discussion, CRS
Report 89-161 ENR, February 1989.
104 Cline, William R. Global Warming: The Economic Stakes. Washington D.C.: Institute
for International Economics, May 1992.
105 For example, see Nordhaus, William D. To Slow or Not to Slow: The Economics of the
Greenhouse Effect. The Economic Journal 101, no. 6, 1991. pp. 920-37.
View Page Image


CRS-92
versus quantity" debate in favor of having more cost control over having absolute certainty of
reductions.106
An additional strength of tax mechanisms is that they are self-executing in many ways,
solving some of the implementation problems raised by regulatory systems. For example, if the
tax were imposed on fuel inputs (e.g., coal, oil, and natural gas), little additional data collection
would be necessary to impose the tax; no cumbersome or expensive monitoring systems, such
as stack monitoring, would be necessary to determine emission levels and potential tax
liability.107 Other transaction costs, such as tracking credits under a tradeable permit program,
would be unnecessary. Once set up, legal challenges and the delays resulting from legal
proceedings might lessen. This would be particularly true if farther down the line it were decided
that increased reductions in CO2 were necessary. With a carbon tax system, focus would be on
changing the tax rate, compared with a tradeable credit program where concern about legal rights
and "takings" or disruption of any credit market or corporate compliance planning could be
involved. Like a tradeable permit system, a carbon tax system could also stimulate development
of a wide range of cost-effective control measures as specific reductions would be determined
by the balance between control costs and the tax, rather than limited by specific reductions
mandated under a regulatory system.
However, in some ways, a tax system merely changes the forum, rather than the substance
of implementation issues. Because paying a carbon tax becomes an alternative to controlling
emissions, the debate over the amount of reductions necessarily becomes a debate over the tax
level imposed. Those wanting large reductions quickly would want a high tax imposed over a
short period of time. Those more concerned with the potential economic burden of a carbon tax
would want a low tax imposed at a later time with possible exceptions for various events.
Carbon taxes would remain basically an implementation strategy; policy determinations such as
tax levels would require political/regulatory decisions.
Climate change is also a global problem, making at least some international cooperation
on strategies desirable. Current European efforts to begin addressing CO2 emissions focus on
a carbon tax or a hybrid carbon tax/energy tax. The European Community (EC) had proposed
a $3 per barrel of oil equivalent tax beginning in 1993, rising to $10 per barrel by 2000. Fifty
percent of the tax would be imposed on energy production (including nuclear power) except
renewables; fifty percent of the tax would be based on carbon emissions. This choice of a hybrid
tax reflects concern within the EC that energy efficiency be promoted as an explicit goal, and
concern within the environmental community about promoting nuclear power. Although any
U.S. carbon tax would not necessarily be identical to an EC levy--even if the reduction goals
were comparable--using the same general approach would make discussions of comparability
or reciprocity easier.
A final consideration is that a carbon levy would raise money. For example, the proposed
EC tax is estimated to raise about $63 billion annually by the year 2000. What governments
choose to do with that money would have some influence on the macroeconomic effects of a CO2
106 Of course, this is no guarantee that once a carbon tax level were set that it would not be
adjusted in the future as desired reduction levels are achieved or not achieved.
107 However, substantial data needs would be required if one endeavors to measure net social
costs and benefits, for example to validate the achievement of maximized net social welfare.
View Page Image


CRS-93
reduction program. In any case, the revenue could provide the governments involved with
flexibility in addressing economic concerns within their countries and between the industrialized
countries and the developing countries. On the latter point, funds might be allocated from the
revenue received to encourage programs to control global warming gases (or to promote
sustainable development and species preservation, for example) in Third World countries. In
addition, the carbon tax approach would not involve massive government intervention in terms
of direct regulation. Of course, it is a tax whose effects would be particularly felt by energy-
intensive industries.
In dealing with the complex and global nature of climate change, carbon taxes have some
important strengths in terms of economic efficiency, implementation, cost control, and potential
international harmonization. As a tax, a carbon levy would result in revenues being created for
the government--the disposition of which would have a substantial impact on the economic
effects of the tax.
Effluent Fees
From topics discussed at public conferences108 to initiatives endorsed by the109
Administration, market-based alternatives to conventional environmental regulation have
moved out of the economics journals and into the policy debates. In the policy area, market-
based strategies for water pollution control are a topic of somewhat more recent interest than
related areas such as air pollution control. Two basic options are the focus of much of the
attention: effluent charges, which put a price on each unit of discharge, and tradable permits of
the sort already endorsed in diverse regions such as the Tar-Pamlico river basin of North Carolina
and the Dillon Reservoir in Colorado (see discussions in previous section of this report). Effluent
fees or charges are a newer instrument in the water pollution control field, even for
demonstration purposes.
In 1990 direct and indirect releases of toxic pollutants to water by manufacturing facilities
amounted to 645 million pounds, according to reports of facilities subject to the Toxics Release
Inventory (TRI) established by section 313 of the Superfund Amendments and Reauthorization
Act of 1986.110 Releases of conventional pollutants, though not reported pursuant to TRI, are
estimated at an additional 3.4 million pounds. That volume of discharges, of both toxic and
conventional pollutants, although regulated by traditional permit and control measures, is
responsible for widespread impairment of the Nation's waters. Water pollution injures animal
108 See, for example: U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Water. Clean Water
and the American Economy, Proceedings of a Conference, Oct. 19-21, 1992. EPA 800-R-

001a. March 1993. 2 vol.


109 See, Gore, Al. Creating a Government that Works Better & Costs Less, Report of the
National Performance Review. September 1993. p. 63. This report notes that market
mechanisms -- fees on pollution, trading systems, and deposit-rebate systems -- can be effective
alternatives to environmental regulation, and it recommends that EPA and Congress use
administrative and legislative measures, for example, the Clean Water Act, to promote market
mechanisms to abate pollution.
110 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, Office of Pollution Prevent and Toxics. 1990
Toxics Release Inventory. EPA 700-S-92-002. May 1992. 229 p.
View Page Image


CRS-94
and plant life and exposes humans to health risks. As a supplement to command-and-control
systems, water pollution discharge fees can give polluters a strong incentive to change their
behavior and reduce the volume and toxicity of wastewater.
Background
Economists argue for effluent fees as a way to internalize external social costs, and a well-
designed fee or charge system should incorporate evaluation of potential benefits (avoided
damages) in a structure that accurately accounts for all sources of those damages. In the 103rd
Congress legislation has been introduced that would impose effluent fees on industrial
wastewater discharges in order to generate revenue for water quality programs, H.R. 2199 and111
H.R. 2255. The legislation proposes to raise $2 billion annually by assessing a charge on a
specified group of chemicals (300 toxic and three conventional pollutants) released to surface
water by industrial direct dischargers and indirect dischargers (companies that discharge wastes
to municipal sewers for treatment by the local sewerage utility) throughout the United States.
The legislation has dual objectives -- a specified revenue goal for water quality programs raised
through a "polluter pays" fee system.
Under the proposal, the pollutants are grouped in five categories consisting of a base group
and four other groups that reflect increasing toxicity to aquatic life and human health. A fee rate
is established for each of the five categories that would be applied to actual loadings, or
discharges, of the individual chemicals. Toxicity characteristics, developed by EPA in
connection with standard setting under the Clean Water Act, yield a toxic weighting factor for
each pollutant and, hence, a means of ranking and grouping the chemicals according to their
relative toxicities.
Implementation Issues
Two key issues associated with the proposals are identifying which chemicals would be
subject to effluent fees and determining the rate or rates applicable to discharges of those
chemicals. A discharge fee can be applied most easily to discharges from point sources, since
the discharges can be accurately measured or calculated. Measurement or calculation based on
actual or estimated discharges is essential. Also important is basing the proposal on as
comprehensive a list of chemicals as possible, so that all pollutants with potential for causing
environmental harm are made subject to the same manner of incentives to reduce damages.
The chemical list in the legislation includes three conventional pollutants (total suspended
solids, biological oxygen demand, and oil and grease) because discharges of these substances can
impair water quality and because they provide a reference point for relative toxicity of the other
chemicals. They include metals and metal compounds, organic chemicals, non-metallic
inorganics, pesticides, and acids, bases and salts. The toxic pollutants include chemicals from
several lists: pollutants included in TRI reporting requirements and known to be discharged to
surface waters; chemicals regulated as priority pollutants under the Clean Water Act; and
111 H.R. 2199 was introduced Rep. Gerry Studds and was referred to the Committees on
Merchant Marine and Fisheries and Public Works and Transportation. H.R. 2255, introduced
by Rep. Norman Mineta and referred to the Public Works and Transportation Committee, is
substantially the same (including the tax proposals discussed here) except for provisions affecting
jurisdiction of the Merchant Marine and Fisheries Committee.
View Page Image


CRS-95
chemicals of more recent concern because of their potential to accumulate in living organisms
and become more concentrated as they move up the food chain (through bioaccumulation or
biomagnification) which are not currently covered by either TRI or Clean Water Act regulations.
This substantially addresses the issue of a data set that is both comprehensive and current.
Fundamental to the proposal is the concept that the rate of fee or charge should be tied to
the environmental harm or threat of harm caused by the discharge of the pollutants. Thus, the
toxicity of the substance is important as a basis for determining the fee. Under the legislation,
toxic weighting factors are used to rank each chemical and place it in a group, for purposes of
determining the applicable effluent fee. EPA uses toxic weighting factors in the process of
evaluating technological options under the industrial point source regulatory program. The
analysis reflects the fact that some pollutants are more toxic than others and removal of pollutants
by one technology may be more or less effective than another technology based on its ability to
remove the more toxic chemicals. A weighting factor for a pollutant parameter is calculated in
relation to a selected standard pollutant (e.g., copper).
EPA has developed toxic weighting factors for 126 priority pollutants and approximately
250 pesticides, but no toxic weighting factors have been developed for a number of chemicals
listed in the legislation. Thus, in the proposal, those chemicals were assigned a proxy factor. For
those chemicals, this results in a somewhat arbitrary assignment or ranking; actual toxic
weighting factors, if available, could easily be lower or higher.
Use of EPA's toxic weighting factors is an imperfect strategy for ranking the toxicity of
chemicals, since it does not cover all chemicals of potential interest or concern. Other ranking
systems might take into account a range of parameters such as toxic effects (acute and chronic
toxicity, wildlife and human health toxicity), environmental fate (persistence), and exposure data
(detection in water and sediments). Inclusion of multiple parameters has the potential to
strengthen the results of chemical ranking, but sufficient data in this broad array of categories and
for all pollutants of concern do not currently exist.
Effluent fee rates under the legislation are based on the categories of chemicals, their
relative toxicity to one another, and the amount of total revenue to be collected. A rate of 0.6
cents per pound of pollutant discharge is set for chemicals in the base category (Group 1), which
consists primarily of conventional pollutants and others with very low toxicity. Each of the other
categories' fee rates is then established in relation to the base rate in order to reflect relative
toxicity. The rate of fee for chemicals discharged in Group 5 (consisting of chemicals with the
highest toxicity) would be a fee of $63.39 per pound discharged.
Impacts
The objective of the proposed industrial wastewater effluent fee is revenue generation, but
if a quantity- and toxicity-based discharge fee program were implemented, polluters' residuals
management practices would be expected to change because the fees would increase the cost to
polluters of using surface waters as a waste disposal medium. The changes in polluters' behavior
would depend on the magnitude of the fee and discharge abatement costs. Thus far, little or no
empirical study has been done on what level(s) of fee(s) would result in reduced discharges.
View Page Image


CRS-96
Faced with a discharge fee, the polluter has five possible adaptations.112 First, the polluter
can treat its wastewater to reduce the quantity and toxicity of discharges. Many would probably
choose this response, in particular by installing additional control equipment. Second, the
polluter can alter production processes (substitution of less toxic chemical inputs or processes
involving reduced wastewater discharges), which in turn can reduce the quantity and toxicity of
discharges. This response amounts to greater use of pollution prevention as a waste minimization
technique. Third, the polluter can follow some combination of these actions.
Fourth, the polluter can simply pay the fee or charge, postponing a change in residuals
management until the fee increases or abatement costs decrease sufficiently. The revenue goals
estimated for the proposal ($2 billion per year) assume, in fact, that this will be the response of
most industrial sources, since the proposed fee rate for most chemicals is low enough that paying
the fee would generally have minor impact on individual firms or most industry categories. With
the exception of the chemicals and allied products industries (which accounted for 63 percent of
TRI discharges in 1990 and would pay about two-thirds of fees paid by all industries under the113
proposal), impacts on most industries would not be significant.
Finally, the polluter could reduce production or close down.
To the extent that revenue-raising is a key objective of an effluent fee (rather than purely
as an economic incentive to dischargers), it is necessary to build into the fee system a means for
making adjustments over time. For example, to maintain a predictable revenue stream -- where
that is the goal -- the design of the system should provide for periodic changes in the fee rates
to account for effects of inflation. Similarly, the fee system needs to recognize and adjust for
uncertainties in its initial design. One major uncertainty could result if the fees in fact have the
effect of altering polluters' actions, that is, if imposition of fees led to reduction in use of the
chemicals and revenues were to decline. While it is difficult to estimate the extent to which
chemical use would be altered, the potential for reduced revenue should be considered.
Input Fees - Fertilizer, Pesticide and Animal Feed Tax
Background
Policy interest in taxing inputs to agricultural runoff also is reflected in the same legislative
proposals, H.R. 2199/H.R. 2255. The legislation recognizes that surface and ground waters are
potentially vulnerable to contamination by various types of runoff from agricultural lands and
activities. When pesticides and fertilizers are applied to crops, rangeland, forests, urban
landscapes, and other lands, they may be transported by wind, rainfall, runoff, and infiltration.
Chemicals dissolved in runoff water are carried to nearby surface water or may enter
112 Morton, Brian J., Ian Burns, Jenny Dempsey, Kristy Mathews, Tayler Bingham. Effluent
Charges and Water Quality: A Preliminary Assessment. Draft report prepared by the Center
For Economics Research, Research Triangle Institute for the US EPA Office of Water. May

1992. pp. 6-20 - 6-23.


113 Congressional Research Service, U.S. Library of Congress. Funding Water Quality
Programs: Revenues for a National Clean Water Investment Corporation. Report prepared
for the House Committee on Merchant Marine and Fisheries, Subcommittee on Fisheries and
Wildlife Conservation and the Environment. July 1992. pp. 14-15.
View Page Image


CRS-97
groundwater through direct infiltration, as well as through sinkholes or abandoned wells.
Another significant source of surface and groundwater pollution is animal waste runoff,
estimated to account for over one-third of all agricultural nonpoint source pollution and causing
impairments of water bodies in 32 States.
Implementation Issues
This legislation would impose taxes on three sources of this nonpoint source pollution
runoff, pesticide active ingredients, the nutrient content of fertilizer chemicals, and processed
animal feed in order to generate revenues to support water quality programs. The concept
underlying the legislation is to generate revenues that would be dedicated to supporting water
pollution control programs authorized by the Clean Water Act, including projects to control
nonpoint sources of pollution. It embodies the "polluter pays" principle of charging the polluter
in some proportion to his contribution to the problem of environmental contamination or
degradation. Those who use the most fertilizers, pesticides, or animal feed would pay the bulk
of the cost.
There are about 750 actual active ingredients used in pesticides which would be covered
by the legislative proposal and would be taxed at a rate of 24.27 cents per pound of active
ingredient in the pesticide. These active ingredients are formulated into more than 20,000
individual products. Two plant chemicals that constitute the nutrient content of fertilizers
(nitrogen and phosphorus) are of concern environmentally and would be subject to the tax
proposal. Fertilizer chemicals would be taxed at a rate of 0.845 cents per pound of nitrogen or
phosphorus. Finally, processed animal feed would be taxed at a rate of $2.68 per ton.
Impacts
As true economic incentives, the pesticide, fertilizer, and animal feed taxes proposed in the
legislation are rather blunt instruments. The principal purpose of the taxes is revenue generation,
and the individual tax rates were set at levels necessary to generate specified revenue goals ($500
million from the tax on pesticide active ingredients, and $250 million each from the fertilizer and
animal feed taxes), based on production volume data used in the analysis. With the defined
revenue goal of the legislation, plus the relative inelasticity of demand for the three types of
products, it is quite likely that these tax rates are set at levels that are too low to affect use
significantly. Consequently, any chemical use reductions due to the taxes would be an indirect
result of the legislation.
To be more precise economic incentive tools, the tax rates might incorporate factors to
reflect the degree of human health or environmental harm from the pesticide, fertilizer, or animal
waste runoff, such as calculating something like a toxicity weighting factor. In the case of
fertilizers, such a calculation would need to reflect a range of potential environmental damages,
including both toxicity (for example, public health concerns of nitrates in groundwater) and over
enrichment of surface waters. Likewise, in the case of animal feed, a tax rate set reflect the
environmental and health effects of livestock wastes should account for both the pathogens and
nutrients in the waste.
For pesticides, analytic approaches to ranking the active ingredients in order to reflect
environmental harm or toxicity might be explored. One option might be to rank pesticide active
ingredients according to their LD50 ratings. (LD50 is a commonly used technique that measures
the concentration of a chemical that will produce a lethal dose to 50 percent of a test species; the
View Page Image


CRS-98
results of LD50 tests are one of the required data sets used in EPA's pesticides registration
process.) Further, toxicity rankings such as this might be combined with rankings of the
chemicals' potential for leaching to groundwater or for surface water runoff, to yield a somewhat
broader ranking system for pesticides.
The outcome of these environmental tax proposals is uncertain. There is, of course, strong
opposition to imposing new taxes, even for specified, dedicated purposes such as pollution
control programs. In addition, a particular concern of those who would pay the bulk of these
taxes, the agricultural community, is that under the legislation as much as 85 percent of the
revenues would go to controlling non-agricultural sources of water pollution (capital
improvements to publicly owned sewage treatment works).
User Taxes - Water Use Tax
Background
The same legislation, H.R. 2199/H.R. 2255, also proposes a water use tax as a form of
wastewater discharger fee. Under the legislative proposal, commercial and industrial water use
would be taxed at a rate of 1.95 cents per thousand gallons of water used. The objective of the
tax is revenue generation (estimated by bill sponsors to be $1 billion per year, based on 1990
water usage by those sectors), with revenues to be dedicated to water pollution control programs,
particularly capital investments in wastewater treatment construction.
Implementation Issues
The concept underlying this tax is that users of wastewater services contribute to water
pollution, and users benefit from the services of wastewater treatment -- either directly if they
are connected to public sewerage facilities, or indirectly if they discharge to waterways or
septage systems. (The tax charges the user for the privilege of discharging to waterways or
groundwater.)114 Water use is the basis of this tax, since the quantity of water released or
discharged is a function of water consumed. In general, water use is measured (even where water
is self-supplied), while the quantity of water discharged may or may not be measured --
particularly for discharges through public sewerage systems.
Impacts
The long run price elasticity of demand (the measure of sensitivity to price changes) for115
water has been estimated at between 0.5 and 0.8 for industrial users. That is, a 10 percent
increase in price would lead to a drop in industrial demand of 8 percent or less. Over the long
114 Apogee Research, Inc. An Inventory of Financing Options for the Albemarle-Pamlico
Sound. December 1991. p. 51.
115 Boland, John J., Benedykt Dziegielewski, Duane D. Baumann, and Eva M. Optiz.
"Influence of Price and Rate Structures on Municipal and Industrial Water Use," a report
submitted to the U.S. Army Corps of Engineers Institute for Water Resources, June 1984, p. 6,
in Apogee Research, Inc. America's Environmental Infrastructure: A Water and Wastewater
Investment Study, prepared for the Clean Water Council. 1990. p. 36.
View Page Image


CRS-99
term, less water use would represent resource savings, but it also would erode the anticipated
revenue goal in this portion of the legislative proposal.
Excluding some user sectors from the tax weakens the incentive basis of the proposal. In
particular, irrigation use by agriculture represented 40 percent of all freshwater withdrawals in
1990 and was the largest sector use.116 Both the infrastructure associated with the systems that
deliver water to irrigated agriculture and the discharges or return flow from irrigation represent
economic and environmental costs to society which could be better internalized through more
accurate price signals to those users. In contrast, industrial and commercial use which are
included in the water use tax proposal represented just 6.4 percent of 1990 water use but a larger
share (28 percent) of public-supply deliveries in 1990.117
Wetlands Mitigation Banking
Interest has grown recently in creating wetlands mitigation banks, in which wetlands are
created, restored, or enhanced expressly for the purpose of compensating for unavoidable
wetland losses associated with development actions. Units of restored or created wetlands are
expressed as "credits" and accumulated credits are subsequently withdrawn to offset "debits"
incurred at the development site. While more than 100 such banks are either actively operating
or are being developed, so far there has been little Federal guidance on mitigation bank
objectives, methods of determining credits and debits, and other implementation issues.
Background
In August 1993 the Clinton Administration announced a series of initiatives that constitute
a comprehensive reform of wetlands policies and embody a number of regulatory, administrative,
and legislative details. The proposal includes support for the use of mitigation banking in
appropriate circumstances as a means of compensating for wetlands impacts authorized by
wetlands regulatory programs. The Administration proposed several actions to ensure that
mitigation of environmental impacts within Federal regulatory programs is effective and
predictable.
First, the Army Corps of Engineers, which issues permits for activities in wetlands under
the Clean Water Act Section 404 program, is to issue guidance to field staff to clarify the
requirements for developing compensatory mitigation conditions in Section 404 permits.
Second, the Administration endorsed in the policy the use of mitigation banking under the
Section 404 program. The Administration noted that while a number of technical and procedural
questions remain regarding the establishment and long-term management of mitigation banks,
the concept offers numerous advantages, if carried out with appropriate environmental
116 Solley, Wayne B., Robert R. Pierce, Howard A. Perlman. U.S. Geological Survey, U.S.
Department of the Interior. Estimated Use of Water in the United States in 1990. U.S.
Geological Survey Circular 1081. 1993. 76 p.
117 Ibid., p. 22. Public supply refers to water withdrawn by public and private water suppliers
and delivered to multiple users for domestic, commercial, industrial, and thermoelectric power
uses. Public supply withdrawals represented 11 percent of freshwater withdrawals for all off
stream categories in 1990.
View Page Image


CRS-100
safeguards. Banks are often ecologically advantageous because they consolidate fragmented
wetland mitigation projects into one large contiguous parcel that can more effectively replace the
lost wetland functions within a watershed. Mitigation banks also provide a framework for
financial resources, planning, and technical expertise to be brought together in a fashion often
not possible with smaller mitigation projects.118
Third, the Corps and EPA (which shares responsibility for administering Section 404)
issued guidance to field staff to clarify the manner in which wetlands mitigation banking is
appropriately used within the Section 404 program. This guidance is intended to provide interim
direction pending the results of additional studies to encourage the use of mitigation banks for
compensatory mitigation under Section 404.
Finally, the Administration requested that Congress endorse the appropriate use of banking
as a compensatory mitigation option under Section 404. Two bills introduced in the 103rd
Congress to amend Section 404 of the Clean Water Act address mitigation banking.
H.R. 1330 includes a provision directing that mitigation banking programs be established
in each State. Under the bill, these programs would provide for crediting contributions to the
mitigation bank in land, cash, or in-kind contributions so that persons unable to sponsor specific
mitigation projects can contribute to the bank. The programs also would be required to ensure
completion and maintenance of mitigation projects for at least a 25-year period and would limit
activities on wetlands that are part of a mitigation bank to uses that are consistent with
maintaining or gaining significant wetlands values and functions.
S. 1304 authorizes the use of mitigation banks within the context of appropriate safeguards.
In part, this proposal is intended to set certain boundaries on ongoing mitigation banking
practices to improve their operation while protecting wetlands values. Under this legislation, the
Corps and EPA would issue rules governing establishment, use, maintenance, and oversight of
mitigation banks. Among the requirements, mitigation banks would need to ensure that
consistent and scientifically-sound methods are used to determine credits and debits at the site
of proposed permits and sites of mitigation banks. In addition, fees charged for participation in
the bank would be based on the full costs of replacing lost wetlands functions and acreage,
including the costs of land acquisition, management measures, long-term maintenance, potential
remediation of project failure, and other relevant factors.
Implementation Issues
The proponents of mitigation banks have been enthusiastic about the potential for their use
in allowing development projects to proceed without costly regulatory delays and to minimize
planning and design costs by pooling what would otherwise be several smaller mitigation
undertakings. In both respects, mitigation banks may serve the purpose of allowing economic
development to proceed while minimizing the loss of (and possibly maximizing the increase of)
environmental benefits to society.
Still, a number of implementation issues are apparent that lead to uncertainties about the
success of the concept. Prominent among the issues is that determining the success of a
118 "Protecting America's Wetlands: A Fair, Flexible, and Effective Approach," in Bureau of
National Affairs, Inc., Daily Environment Report, No. 163, Aug. 25, 1993, p. E-9.
View Page Image


CRS-101
mitigation bank is a very complex task, and considerable uncertainty exists surrounding the
measurement of functional values. None of the traditional wetlands management techniques are
totally proven, and all possess limitations which sometimes detract from their utility in wetlands
mitigation banking. Wetlands creation is regarded in scientific circles as a still somewhat
experimental technique. While wetlands restoration and enhancement exist as the surest
techniques for the purposes of mitigation banking, the slow rate at which many wetlands actually
return to the natural state or to an enhanced condition and begin to amass bankable credits has
also been a problem in several cases.119
The use of preservation as a means to compensate wetlands losses is a particularly
contentious point among those who argue the pros and cons of wetlands mitigation. Preservation
of existing wetlands areas for compensation purposes becomes a valid consideration only when
it can be shown that the wetlands in the preservation area would be lost in the absence of
preservation. Otherwise, wetlands would not be replaced, and in fact, a net reduction in wetlands
would result. Further, wetlands restoration or creation costs vary significantly. They range from
as low as several hundred dollars per acre for restoring wetlands in the Prairie Pothole region of
the central United States to tens or hundreds of thousands of dollars per acre for some coastal
wetlands. At the high end in particular, sponsorship of mitigation banks will hinge on the
perceived certainty of credit accrual.
Impacts
The Administration's August 1993 policy endorsement and legislative clarification could
give guidance on the establishment and operation of banks that some observers believe is
lacking. If appropriately bounded, wetlands mitigation banking can benefit developers by
allowing economic activity to proceed more efficiently, while providing a realistic mechanism
for permanently preserving areas that might otherwise not be protected. Banking also increases
the likelihood that mitigation can be incorporated into local or regional comprehensive planning
objectives.
On the other hand, the use of mitigation banking introduces risk into the public's
environmental benefits portfolio -- for example, financial bankruptcy of a sponsor could result
in breaking of a wetlands management contract and curtailment of associated benefits. Further,
establishment of a mitigation bank can be time-consuming and costly and may even introduce
administrative risks into the Section 404 permit review process if a permit application were
denied even after resources were invested in the mitigation banking. In the long run, good
project planning may be neglected, and banked credits may be resorted to instead of avoidance
and minimization of impacts.
Assurance Bonding To Reduce Agricultural Nonpoint Source Pollution
Background
One method of incorporating the social cost of water pollution into dischargers' decision
making is to require dischargers to purchase dated assurance bonds that reflect the full value of
potential worst-case costs to remediate environmental damage resulting from their actions.
119 Reppert, Richard. Institute for Water Resources, U.S. Army Corps of Engineers.
Wetlands Mitigation Banking Concepts. IWR Report 92-WMB-1, July 1992. p. 13
View Page Image


CRS-102
Where water quality degradation could be linked directly to one or a small number of
agribusinesses, they could be required to post assurance bonds. The bond would be repaid in full
(possibly with interest) at the time of maturity if the bondholder demonstrates that the potential
damage has not occurred. It would be repaid in part if some level of damage less than the
potential baseline has occurred and would be forfeited if worst-case damages are incurred.
This market-based approach is designed to resolve a specific problem in environmental
quality: reducing potential damages under conditions of uncertainty. In the context of
agricultural nonpoint source pollution, assurance bonds can facilitate internalization of costs in
several ways. First, the farmer is responsible for choosing and implementing agricultural
practices that reduce water quality damages, providing flexibility to encourage innovation by the
farmer. Second, the farmer is responsible for demonstrating the water quality damages did not
occur. Thus, public monitoring and enforcement costs could be less than under traditional
approaches. Third, interest from the bond pool could also generate additional monies for water
quality protection. The most striking feature of the approach is the incentive it offers both public120
and private entities to improve the data on the environmental costs of economic activity.
Implementation Issues
An assurance bonding requirement would be administered by an appropriate public agency.
State water quality regulatory agencies could act as the bonding agency. Several conditions
could give rise to the utility of an assurance bonding approach: uncertainty over availability of
control technologies and methods; uncertainty over water quality benefits derived from control
efforts; and uncertainty over relative contributions from different sources. Several types of
activities fulfill one or more of these criteria, including nonpoint source discharges of
conventional and unconventional pollutants from agricultural, silvicultural, mining, and
development activities.
To determine the value of the assurance bonds, the bonding agency would base its decision
on existing scientific information reflecting the monetary value of either repairing and
rehabilitating the worst-case environmental damage or providing an alternative to normal
services, such as drinking water. The bonds would be required to be purchased annually for a
continuous discharge, and the value of the bond could change to reflect changes in potential
damages, repair costs, or inflation. The bonds would be held for a specified period that reflected
the anticipated lag time in the expression of potential damage.
Impacts
Potential benefits of an assurance bonding approach include giving dischargers an incentive
to minimize discharges and flexibility to determine the most efficient means and levels of
control, while giving environmental agencies sufficient funds to clean up damage resulting from
any discharges.
120 Costanza, Robert, and Charles Perrings. "A Flexible Assurance Bonding System for
Improved Environmental Management." Ecological Economics. v. 2, 1990. p. 69.
View Page Image


CRS-103
A number of potential drawbacks also exist.121 First, setting the value of the bond, even
with the benefit of scientific information, would essentially be a subjective decision dependent
on numerous assumptions. The bonding agency could be subjected to political pressures or legal
challenge to its actions, thus requiring extensive administrative expense and documentation.
Scientific uncertainty that could be expected in many cases creates an additional problem
because there must be legal justification for withholding all or part of the bond.
Second, because it is based on the cost of remediation or replacement, the value of the
assurance bond would not necessarily capture the social cost of permanent environmental
damage. Basing the value of the bond on some measure of the value of environmental damages
poses numerous methodological problems.
Third, an additional cost of the assurance bond is the opportunity cost of the capital tied up
in the bond. This might be unaffordable for all but the largest farmers.
Investment Tax Credits for Recycling
Historically, tax credits have been used in a variety of areas to encourage certain types of
investment. Federal, State, or local governments could offer investment tax credits for the
purchase of recycling equipment. Such credits would encourage increased private capital
investment in recycling. Firms would be more likely to make capital investments in recycling
because the tax credit would effectively reduce the cost of purchasing new recycling equipment.
Background
A bill that would provide a 25 percent investment tax credit for the purchase of recycling
equipment was introduced in the First Session of the 103rd Congress. The tax credit would allow
businesses that purchase recycling equipment to deduct 25 percent of the cost from their total tax
liability. Recycling equipment is defined in the Internal Revenue Code of 1986 as any equipment
used exclusively to sort and prepare solid waste for recycling or in the recycling of solid waste.122
The tax credit would also be available for equipment used in processing some virgin material,
as long as the virgin material is less than 10 percent of the total material processed by the
equipment. Finally, the credit would be allowed for equipment used in the conversion of solid
waste into fuel or energy.
Implementation Issues
If firms took advantage of the tax credit and purchased more recycling equipment,
recycling capacity would increase, causing an increase in the demand for recyclable materials
(e.g., old newspaper, glass bottles, aluminum and steel cans, and plastic milk and soda bottles).
The impact of increased demand on prices would depend on whether current demand for
recyclable materials exceeds supply. For example, currently more old newspaper is collected
121 U.S. Environmental Protection Agency. "Assurance Bonding for Nonpoint Source
Control." Potential Market Force Mechanisms to Help Achieve Clean Water. Mar. 6, 1991.
pp. 3-5.
122 26 CFR 48(l)(2)(A)(iv)
View Page Image


CRS-104
than paper mills can process because mills do not have enough newspaper deinking machinery.
Paper mills could use the tax credit to purchase enough deinking equipment to match the current
old newspaper supply, causing prices for old newspaper to rise. Alternatively, the market for
high quality glass cullet123 is very strong. High quality cullet can be substituted for other raw
materials in the glass manufacturing process, and recycled glass is produced in the same furnaces
in which virgin glass is made. Recyclers could invest in sorting equipment to produce high
quality cullet and increase the supply of cullet, causing prices to fall.
Any increase in the price of recyclable materials could be offset by increased collection to
keep pace with increased demand. The tax credit could be repealed when enough investment has
taken place to equalize the demand and supply of recyclable materials and when relative prices
of virgin and recycled materials have stabilized.
Allowing the tax credit for equipment used in converting solid waste to fuel or energy
would likely cause increased capital investment for incineration plants. Although incineration
reduces the quantity of waste landfilled it also reduces the amount of recycling. If the investment
tax credit is used primarily for incineration equipment, the legislation could reduce the amount
of waste landfilled and recycled. The types of equipment eligible for the tax credit would need
to be carefully defined to meet the goals of the legislation.
A tax credit is easy to administer because it is virtually self-implementing. However, one
drawback is that it could be costly in terms of lost tax revenue. In addition, the total cost of the
program cannot be determined in advance, but depends on how many businesses purchase new
recycling equipment. As with any tax incentive, enforcement would rely on periodic audits by
Internal Revenue Service personnel to ensure that the credit is only applied to equipment that
meets the eligibility requirements.
Impacts
If prices for recyclable materials increased as a result of a recycling equipment tax credit,
municipalities would benefit because waste disposal and recycling services are typically provided
by local governments. Municipalities often run recycling collection programs at a financial loss
because in some areas the cost of collecting used materials is higher than the revenues that
municipalities receive from the sale of the recyclables. Municipalities that currently offer only
waste disposal services to their residents might begin to provide recycling services if the
proceeds from the sale of recyclable materials could be used to offset the costs of collection or
to make the collection of recyclables profitable.
Businesses likely to benefit from an investment tax credit are those that are already in the
recycling industry and are able to expand by purchasing new equipment or virgin producers who
can change their method of production (e.g., by adding deinking equipment). The tax credit may
not provide enough of an incentive for many new businesses to enter the recycling industry,
especially because startup businesses often show income losses in early years and would not
benefit from the tax credit because they would not have any tax liability. The tax credit also
would not provide any benefit to businesses for investments in recycling equipment prior to the
123 The small pieces of broken glass used to make new glass is called glass cullet. The most
valuable cullet is sorted by color and contains few contaminants such as glass of another color,
or ceramics.
View Page Image


CRS-105
effective date of the credit. This puts existing firms that have made recycling investments at a
disadvantage relative to new firms or existing firms that could use the tax credit to expand. If
few new business take advantage of the tax credit, its impact would be to subsidize investments
that would have been made even in the absence of the credit.
Other Tax Credits for Recycling
In addition to investment tax credits which are meant to spur long term investment, there
are other types of tax credits that have different goals. Tax credits can be developed to favor the
purchase of certain raw materials over others. Governments that want to encourage the use of
recycled products could provide a tax credit applied to the value of recycled products purchased.
Background
A tax credit bill introduced in the 102nd Congress would have amended the Internal
Revenue Code of 1986 to allow newspapers a credit against income tax for using recycled
newsprint. Newspapers would have been allowed a 15 percent tax credit on the amount paid for
recycled newsprint during 1991 and 1992. The credit would have dropped to 10 percent in 1993
and 1994, and 5 percent in 1995 and 1996. The credit would have been phased-out completely
in 1997.
Implementation Issues
The rationale for this policy is that publishers are reluctant to use recycled newsprint
because of perceived differences in price, availability, or quality compared to virgin newsprint.
A tax credit for the purchase of recycled newsprint makes recycled newsprint less expensive
relative to virgin newsprint, encouraging newspaper publishers to purchase more recycled
newsprint. When large newspaper purchasers begin to purchase recycled newsprint, they
enhance the market for recycled newsprint by generating greater demand. As long as mills
continue to increase capacity for deinking old newspaper, the increased demand for old
newspapers would lead to increased newspaper collection and recycling. If the supply expansion
were sufficient, it would further drive down prices for recycled newsprint relative to virgin
newsprint. Eventually, the price differential would reach an optimal level, and the tax credit
would no longer be necessary.
Some paper mills have lower costs for producing recycled newsprint because they are
located closer to the supply of old newspaper and do not incur high shipping costs to receive
recyclable materials. These mills are able to sell recycled newsprint at lower prices than mills
located farther from sources of old newspaper. For example, some Canadian mills incur higher
costs because they purchase old newspaper from the United States then produce recycled
newsprint and ship it back to the United States for use by newspaper publishers. A tax credit that
is fixed nationally does not account for geographical differences in prices. Therefore, the
effectiveness of the tax credit may depend on underlying regional price differences that are
unrelated to the change in tax policy.
Administration of this type of tax credit requires strict recordkeeping by newspaper
publishers and newsprint producers and manufacturers. Because there is no other way to track
sales of recycled newsprint, publishers would need to save newsprint order receipts and
newsprint producers and manufacturers would have to record sales transactions to newspapers.
View Page Image


CRS-106
Another aspect of implementing this tax credit is ensuring that the paper purchased meets
the eligibility requirements. The proposal requires that newsprint contain at least 40 percent
recovered fiber in order to qualify for the tax credit. Because it is impossible to determine the
recovered fiber content of paper by inspecting the finished product, enforcement would depend
on mill certification as to the recycled content of its products, and inspection of the mill's records.
Similar requirements already exist for certifying the recycled content of paper purchased by the
Federal government. In addition, the number of paper mills in North America is relatively small,
making such inspections feasible.
Impacts
This type of proposal would be beneficial in the short run to some participants in the
recycling loop. Collectors could receive higher prices for old newspaper. In addition, mills that
produce recycled paper could experience increased sales. Alternatively, producers of virgin
newsprint could experience a decline in sales.
Whether newspaper publishers would be better off depends on the current price difference
between virgin and recycled newsprint and how prices change in the next five years. The price
of recycled newsprint is currently comparable to the price of virgin newsprint, therefore,
newspaper publishers would gain from the tax credit. Because the percentage of the tax credit
decreases before being phased-out completely, the incentive will become less effective in later
years. Currently, 28 States require newspaper publishers to use recycled newsprint. In these
States, publishers benefit from the tax credit regardless of the relative prices of virgin and
recycled newsprint. However, the tax credit has little incentive effect in these States, it merely
rewards publishers for complying with State law.
Virgin Materials Tax
Virgin materials taxes are used to raise the cost of producing or importing virgin materials.
These taxes aim to make recycled materials more competitive with virgin materials or even less
costly than virgin materials, thus reducing the use of the taxed virgin material.
Background
One bill introduced in the 102nd Congress would have imposed a 4 percent tax on the price
of any paper product sold by a manufacturer, producer, or importer that did not meet minimum
recycled content standards. The minimum recycled content standards would have become more
stringent over time, requiring manufacturers to increase their use of recycled fibers each year to
avoid the tax.
Implementation Issues
The tax would be paid by wholesalers and retailers when they purchase paper products that
do not contain the specified amount of recovered material. The increased cost of these materials
would be passed on to consumers, thus reducing demand for non-recycled paper products.
Producers, manufacturers, and importers would experience reduced sales of paper products with
high virgin content, and would be pressured to switch to production processes that incorporate
higher percentages of recovered materials.
View Page Image


CRS-107
The virgin material tax on paper products is likely to cause some substitution away from
paper products to glass or plastic alternatives. While it would be difficult to substitute another
product for printing and writing paper, it is possible to substitute alternatives for paper packaging
such as plastic milk containers instead of paper, and plastic shrink wrap instead of cardboard
boxes. Because plastics are typically lighter and less bulky than the paper products they replace,
the tax could decrease the amount of waste disposed. For products where substitution is unlikely,
consumers may seek to reduce the amount of the product used. For example, organizations
might try to use electronic mail or use more double-sided copying to reduce their use of printing
and writing paper.
Because the tax is based on paper sales prices, some consumers will shift to less costly
paper products where the total amount of the tax imposed is lower. This does not, however,
change the amount of waste generated. A tax based on total paper weight or volume would
provide a more effective incentive to reduce waste.
The tax could be difficult to administer because of the large number of domestic producers
and manufacturers of paper products. Each producer and manufacturer would need to be able
to verify the recycled content of their products as well as the post-mill, deinked, and post-
consumer waste contents. In addition, each producer and manufacturer would have to track the
amount of taxable products sold in the United States. Producers and manufacturers would
probably be responsible for reporting such amounts and paying the proper tax. Enforcement
would rely on audits performed by Internal Revenue Service personnel to determine if the proper
amount of products sold was reported. In addition, it is difficult to verify recycled content of
paper products based on an inspection of a paper manufacturing site.
Applying the virgin material tax to imported products increases administrative complexity.
Foreign manufacturers would have to know the recycled content of their paper products and the
amounts exported to the United States. Inspections of foreign plants to verify recycled content
claims could not be easily conducted. Applying the tax would be especially difficult for foreign
non-paper products that are shipped in paper packaging such as corrugated cardboard boxes.
Although the importer would be importing the product contained in the box, it would have to
know the recycled content of the box itself or pay the tax on the price of the box.
Impacts
In general, manufacturers of products using virgin materials are made worse off by this
legislation and manufacturers of products that substitute for virgin materials are made better off.
Where recycled paper products are competitive with virgin counterparts, the tax would increase
the demand for recovered paper, driving up the prices paid to collectors for used paper. Because
municipalities often provide community collection services for recovered material, they would
benefit from higher prices paid. Municipalities are likely to expand recycling programs in
response to higher prices.
Unit Pricing
Many local governments have instituted policies that provide individual households with
incentives for reducing waste generated and increasing recycling. These policies ensure that
waste disposal charges reflect the actual cost of disposal. Typically, households are charged a
fixed fee for solid waste collection, or an unknown portion of general revenues are used to pay
for waste disposal. Neither of these methods of paying for solid waste management allows waste
View Page Image


CRS-108
generators to understand the impact of their behavior on waste management costs. Unit pricing
is a method of pricing waste disposal services based on the amount of waste discarded.
Background
Some municipalities sell specially-marked garbage bags in local stores at a price that
includes the cost of waste disposal. Only garbage placed in these bags is picked up by the
municipality. Other communities sell stickers that must be placed on existing garbage cans or
bags before waste is picked up. Seattle has a unit pricing system that has been operating since
the late 1970s where residents purchase subscriptions for a certain level of service (e.g., one, two,
or three cans per week) and pay higher fees for higher levels of service. As a result of recent
increases in these rates, the utility reports that citizens became aware of the cost of solid waste
disposal for the first time. As rates increased, the utility reported that it was overwhelmed by124
calls from customers wanting to reduce their subscription level. Thus, higher prices and rates
that vary with the amount of waste generated appear to have reduced waste generation and
increased recycling. Seattle officials view these incentives as an integral part of reaching the
city's ambitious goal of 60% recycling.
Implementation Issues
Unit pricing can provide a strong incentive for households to recycle. Some communities
report that participation in recycling programs doubled after a unit pricing system was
implemented.125 This effect may be stronger in communities where recyclable materials are
picked up at no charge or at a price substantially lower than the per bag fee. Unit pricing may
also encourage households to reduce the amount of waste they generate by composting yard and
food waste; by purchasing products with less packaging; by purchasing non-disposable items;
or by using items more times before disposal.
A unit pricing system could have some additional unexpected effects. First, it could lead
to increased illegal disposal. Those trying to avoid paying disposal fees could illegally burn their
trash, dump it on others' property, or transport it to other communities where stickers are not
required. It is very difficult to identify and prosecute perpetrators of illegal disposal. In addition,
volume-based unit pricing may not reduce the total weight of garbage disposed if households
merely compact their usual amount of trash and place it in fewer bags.
Administrative complexity of a unit pricing plan is highly variable depending on how the
program is designed. Designing a billing system that accounts for the number of bags disposed
could be complex. Municipalities can avoid billing if they use local stores to sell bags or
stickers. Municipalities would still need an accounting system for tracking the number of
stickers or bags sold and the amount of money received. The inclusion of apartments in the unit
pricing system would also add to administrative complexity because there is no way to monitor
how much trash each individual apartment places in a common dumpster.
124 Gale, Diana H. Seattle: A Case Study in System Planning. Resource Recovery.
December 1988. p. 31.
125 Robert Bracken, North Carolina County Institutes Sticker System, BioCycle, February

1992, p. 37.


View Page Image


CRS-109
Impacts
Individuals who recycle and minimize waste generation benefit from a unit-pricing scheme.
Large families and households that generate large quantities of waste are likely to pay higher
waste disposal fees with a unit pricing system than they would with a fixed waste disposal fee.
Deposit/Refund for Batteries and Other Hazardous Substances
Requiring refundable deposits on the purchase of certain products would encourage
consumers to return the products for refund of the deposit, and proper disposal. Deposit/refund
systems are most appropriate for small consumer items that are often illegally discarded such as
batteries, but variants of the system have also been suggested for small quantity hazardous
wastes, such as solvents. In the latter case, the purpose of the system would be to reverse the
incentives for midnight dumping that are a side effect of the increasing cost of legal disposal,
ease the task of monitoring and enforcement, return valuable materials to manufacturers for
recycling, provide incentives to recapture losses from production processes, and encourage the
substitution of less hazardous materials.
Background
The RCRA reauthorization bill reported by the Senate Committee on Environment and
Public Works in the 102nd Congress included a provision that would require retail sellers of lead
acid batteries to collect a deposit of at least $10 on the sale of any new lead acid battery not
accompanied by the return of a used lead acid battery. A similar provision is contained in S.729,
the Lead Exposure Reduction Act, reported by the same committee in the 103rd Congress.
Consumers who have paid a deposit may receive a refund equal to the amount of the deposit paid
when they return a used lead acid battery of the same type as the battery purchased within 21
days of sale. The proposal would require that any retailer that sells lead acid batteries also accept
them in return. Any unclaimed deposits become the property of the retailers.
Implementation Issues
The most difficult aspect of implementing a deposit/refund system is ensuring that refunds
are only given to those that have paid deposits. Regulations implementing such a system could
require that retailers provide a receipt for any deposit paid and that the receipt be presented when
a battery is returned and a refund is requested.
Several problems would arise if the law did not require a receipt proving that a deposit was
paid in order to receive a refund. First, anyone possessing old lead acid batteries on the effective
date of the law could bring them to any retailer and demand a refund. More refunds would be
requested than deposits paid, causing a financial loss for retailers. There would also be an
incentive to import used lead acid batteries from other countries if the $10 refund would cover
transportation costs and allow the importer to receive a profit. Lack of a receipt requirement
would also encourage battery theft. Because lead acid batteries are easily removed from
automobiles, thieves could steal the batteries and return them for a $10 refund.
Individual battery retailers could experience cashflow problems if there were no
requirement that refunds be collected from the same retailer to which the deposit was paid. At
establishments where the retailer installs a new battery and recovers the old battery, no deposit
would be required. However, when a do-it-yourselfer purchases a lead acid battery from one
View Page Image


CRS-110
retailer and returns it to another, some retailers could end up paying out more in refunds than
they accepted in deposits.
A battery deposit/refund system is self-implementing. Retailers have an incentive to take
deposits when batteries are purchased because they are entitled to keep any unclaimed deposits.
Once the deposit has been paid, the consumer has an incentive to return a used lead acid battery
to receive a refund. Retailers are likely to recycle the batteries received because the lead
contained in used lead acid batteries is typically sold at a price that is high enough to compensate
battery handlers for the cost of shipping used lead acid batteries to recyclers.
Strict recordkeeping by retailers, manufacturers and recyclers would be required for
enforcement. Each party would have to document the amount of deposits received, refunds
disbursed, and lead acid batteries recycled.
Impacts
A deposit/refund system for lead acid batteries would result in a greater number of batteries
being collected, and an increase in the supply of old lead. Secondary lead smelters would be able
to purchase old lead at lower prices. The price of recycled lead would drop relative to virgin
lead. A deposit/refund system would, therefore, have a positive impact on the secondary lead
smelting industry and a negative impact on the primary lead smelting industry.
Other Deposit Refund Systems
Lubricating Oil. Improper disposal of used motor oil is considered an important nonpoint
source of pollution by EPA, with a large share coming from do-it-yourselfers. Deposits on each
quart of oil sold and refunds for return of used oil have been examined as a way to reduce
improper disposal.126 Most of the proposals include a deposit at the time of sale or return of
equal amounts of used oil. Proof of purchase would be required for any refunds for returning
used oil without buying new oil.
Analysts point out two difficulties in using deposit-refund in this context. First, counterfeit
product (stolen or otherwise) could be introduced. The second problem is the effect of
fluctuating oil prices on the incentive for used oil recycling. Below a certain oil price, recyclers
charge for pickup from service stations, so that there is little incentive to collect oil from do-it-127
yourselfers. Thus, regulatory actions would still be needed to assure proper final disposal of
used oil under conditions of fluctuating oil prices.
Industrial Solvents. Some have suggested that industry generates sufficient amounts of
hazardous waste in small enough quantities to warrant consideration for a deposit-refund128
system. As proposed, this system would deal with the approximately 15% of industrial
hazardous wastes that are potentially containerizable and recyclable. Deposits paid to
distributors would be recovered when the spent chemical was returned to designated recycling
126 Anderson, p. 45
127 Anderson, p.5
128 Stavins, p. 64
View Page Image


CRS-111
facilities. If the material has recovery value, an additional payment to users would be made by
recyclers.
In addition to the problem of counterfeit product, qualitative differences in the solvent
content would require extensive testing of returned-product in order for a deposit-refund system
to work.
View Page Image