Estate and Gift Taxes: Economic Issues






Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress



The Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001 (EGTRRA) repeals the estate
tax in 2010. During the phase-out period, the new law increases the exempt amount to $3.5
million by 2009 and lowers the top rate to 45% by 2007. The federal gift tax remains though the
rate is reduced to the top personal income tax rate and the exemption is separate from the estate
tax exemption. After repeal of the estate tax, carryover basis replaces step-up in basis for assets
transferred at death. The legislation includes an exemption from carryover basis for capital gains
of $1.3 million (and an additional $3 million for a surviving spouse). However, the estate tax
provision in EGTRRA automatically sunsets December 31, 2010.
Thus far in the 110th Congress, seven bills to permanently repeal the estate tax have been
introduced in the House and four in the Senate. Seven bills to retain but modify the estate tax
have been introduced in the House and one in the Senate. The repeal bills differ on whether or not
they would preserve the other changes made by EGTRRA to the taxation of gifts and the basis for
inherited assets. The modification bills differ on the level of the exclusion, what year it would
take effect, whether or not it would be indexed for inflation, and whether any unused exclusion
could be carried over to the estate of the surviving spouse. The Treasury has estimated that
repealing the sunset provision of EGTRRA would reduce receipts by $149.7 billion, through

2013.


Supporters of the estate and gift tax cite its contribution to progressivity in the tax system and to
the need for a tax due to the forgiveness of capital gains taxes on appreciated assets held until
death. Arguments are also made that inheritances represent a windfall to heirs that are more
appropriate sources of tax revenue than income earned through work and effort. Critics of the
estate tax argue that it reduces savings and makes it difficult to pass on family businesses. Critics
also argue that death is not an appropriate time to impose a tax; that much wealth has already
been taxed through income taxes; and that complexity of the tax imposes administrative and
compliance burdens that undermine the progressivity of the tax.
The analysis in this study suggests that the estate tax is highly progressive, although progressivity
is undermined by avoidance mechanisms. Neither economic theory nor empirical evidence
indicate that the estate tax is likely to have much effect on savings. Although some family
businesses are burdened by the tax, only a small percentage of estate tax revenues are derived
from family businesses. Even though there are many estate tax avoidance techniques, it also is
possible to reform the tax and reduce these complexities as an alternative to eliminating the tax.
Thus, the evaluation of the estate tax may largely turn on the appropriateness of such a revenue
source and its interaction with incentives for charitable giving, state estate taxes, and capital gains
and other income taxes. This report will be updated as legislative events warrant.






Introduc tion ..................................................................................................................................... 1
How the Estate and Gift Tax Works................................................................................................2
General Rules............................................................................................................................2
Filing Threshold..................................................................................................................2
Gross Estate Value..............................................................................................................3
Allowable Deductions.........................................................................................................3
Taxable Estate.....................................................................................................................3
Rates and Brackets..............................................................................................................3
A Numerical Example.........................................................................................................3
Tentative Estate Tax............................................................................................................4
The Applicable Credit (Unified with Gift Tax before 2004)...............................................4
Federal Credit for State Death Taxes (Eliminated in 2005)................................................4
Net Federal Estate Tax........................................................................................................5
Special Rules for Family Owned Farms and Businesses..........................................................5
The Generation Skipping Transfer Tax.....................................................................................6
Economic Issues..............................................................................................................................6
The Distributional Effect of the Estate and Gift Tax.................................................................6
Vertical Equity....................................................................................................................6
Horizontal Equity................................................................................................................8
Effect on Saving........................................................................................................................8
Altrui st ic ............................................................................................................................. 9
Accidental ......................................................................................................................... 10
Exchange ....................................................................................................................... .... 10
Joy of Giving....................................................................................................................10
Satiation ............................................................................................................................. 11
Empirical Evidence............................................................................................................11
Effect on Farms and Closely Held Businesses.........................................................................11
Target Efficiency...............................................................................................................12
How Many Farm and Small Business Decedents Pay the Tax?........................................13
Other Issues.......................................................................................................................13
Effects of the Marital Deduction.............................................................................................14
A Backstop for the Income Tax...............................................................................................15
Capital Gains.....................................................................................................................15
Owner-Occupied Housing, Life Insurance, and Other Assets..........................................15
Effects of the Charitable Deduction........................................................................................16
Efficiency Effects, Distortions, and Administrative Costs......................................................16
Repeal of Federal Credit for State Estate and Inheritance Taxes............................................19
Policy Options...............................................................................................................................19
Repealing the Estate and Gift Tax...........................................................................................19
Increasing the Credit, Converting to an Exemption, and/or Changing Rates.........................20
Taxing the Capital Gains of Heirs vs. the Estate Tax..............................................................20
Concerns of Farms and Family Businesses.............................................................................21
Reform Proposals and Other Structural Changes....................................................................21
Conclusion ..................................................................................................................................... 24





Table 1. Numerical Example...........................................................................................................4
Table 2. Numerical Example Continued with Taxes and Credits....................................................5
Table 3. Estate Tax Deductions and Burdens, 2006........................................................................7
Table 4. Theoretical Effect of Estate Tax on Saving, By Bequest Motive....................................10
Table A-1. The Filing Requirement and Unified Credit................................................................25
Table A-2. Gross Estate Value for Returns Filed in 2006..............................................................25
Table A-3. Allowable Deductions on 2006 Returns......................................................................25
Table A-4. 2008 Estate Tax Rate Schedule....................................................................................26
Table A-5. Repealed Credit for State Death Taxes........................................................................26
Table A-6. Wealth Distribution of Taxable Returns Filed in 2006................................................27
Appendix. Estate and Gift Tax Data..............................................................................................25
Author Contact Information..........................................................................................................27






The estate and gift tax has been and will continue to be the subject of significant legislative
interest. The “Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001” (EGTRRA, P.L.
107-16) repeals the estate tax after 2009. However, the legislation sunsets after 2010 reverting
back to the law as it existed in 2001. Congress could eliminate the sunset provision in EGTRRA,
thus making repeal of the estate tax permanent. Repeal of the sunset would retain the EGTRRA
changes to the taxation of capital gains of inherited assets and the gift tax.
Immediate repeal of the estate and gift tax in 2001 would have cost up to $662 billion (over 10
years), an amount in excess of the projected estate tax yield of $409 billion because of projected
behavioral responses that would also lower income tax revenues (e.g. more life time transfers to
donees in lower tax brackets, more purchase of life insurance with deferral aspects, and lower
compliance). Repealing the EGTRRA sunset would cost $522 billion over the 2009-2018 budget
window. Most of the revenue loss is in the “out” years; $149.7 billion over 2009 to 2013 and 1
$372.3 billion over 2014 to 2018. Immediate repeal (as opposed to eventual repeal beyond 2010)
would be more expensive.
Thus far in the 110th Congress, seven bills to permanently repeal the estate tax have been
introduced in the House and four in the Senate. Seven bills to retain but modify the estate tax
have been introduced in the House and one in the Senate. The repeal bills differ on whether or not
they would preserve the other changes made by EGTRRA to the taxation of gifts and the basis for
inherited assets. The modification bills differ on the level of the exclusion, what year it would
take effect, whether or not it would be indexed for inflation, and whether any unused exclusion
could be carried over to the estate of the surviving spouse. No potential revenue loss estimates are
available for these proposals.
Proponents of an estate and gift tax argue that it contributes to progressivity in the tax system by
“taxing the rich.” (Note, however, that there is no way to objectively determine the optimal
degree of progressivity in a tax system). A related argument is that the tax reduces the 2
concentration of wealth and its perceived adverse consequences for society. Moreover, while the
estate and gift tax is relatively small as a revenue source (yielding $26 billion in 2007 and
accounting for 1% of federal revenue), it raises a not insignificant amount of revenue—revenue
that could increase in the future due to strong performance of stock market and growth in inter-
generational transfers as the baby boom generation ages. Eliminating or reducing the tax would
either require some other tax to be increased, some spending program to be reduced, or an
increase in the national debt.
In addition, to the extent that inherited wealth is seen as windfall to the recipient, such a tax may
be seen by some as fairer than taxing earnings that are the result of work and effort. Finally, many
economists suggest that an important rationale for maintaining an estate tax is the escape of
unrealized capital gains from any taxation, since heirs receive a stepped-up basis of assets.
Families that accrue large gains through the appreciation of their wealth in assets can, in the

1 U.S. Department of the Treasury, General Explanations of the Administration’s Fiscal Year 2009 Revenue Proposals,
Washington, Feb. 2008, p. 129.
2 Possible consequences that have been discussed include concentrations of political power, inefficient investments by
the very wealthy, and disincentives to work by heirs (often referred to as the Carnegie conjecture, reflecting a claim
argued by Andrew Carnegie).





absence of an estate tax, largely escape any taxes on these gains by passing on the assets to their
heirs.
The estate tax also encourages giving to charity, since charitable contributions are deductible
from the estate tax base. Since charitable giving is generally recognized as an appropriate object
of subsidy, the presence of an estate tax with such a deduction may be seen as one of the potential
tools for encouraging charitable giving.
Critics of the estate and gift tax typically make two major arguments: the estate and gift tax
discourages savings and investments, and the tax imposes an undue burden on closely held family
businesses (including farms). In the latter case, the argument is made that the estate tax forces the
break-up of family businesses without adequate liquidity to pay the tax. Critics also suggest that
the estate and gift tax is flawed as a method of introducing progressivity because there are many
methods of avoiding the tax, methods that are more available to very wealthy families (although
this criticism could support reform of the tax as well as repeal). A related criticism is that the
administrative and compliance cost of an estate and gift tax is onerous relative to its yield (again,
however, this argument could also be advanced to support reform rather than repeal). In general,
there may also be a feeling that death is not a desirable time to impose a tax; indeed, the critics of
the estate and gift tax often refer to the tax as a death tax. Critics also argue that some of the
wealth passed on in estates has generally already been subject to capital income taxes.
The remainder of this report, following a brief explanation of how the tax operates, analyzes these
arguments for and against the tax. The report concludes with an inventory and discussion of
alternative policy options.

The unified estate and gift tax is levied on the transfer of assets that occurs when someone dies or
gives a gift. Filing an estate tax return can be difficult depending on the value and complexity of
the estate. The purpose here is to outline the mechanics of the estate and gift tax. The first section
begins with a brief review of the general rules accompanied with a numerical example. There are
some minor provisions of the law that are not discussed here, however, such as the phase out of 3
the graduated rates and the credit for taxes on property recently transferred. The second section
summarizes the special rules for farms and small businesses. And, the final section briefly
describes the generation skipping transfer tax. The appendix of this report provides detailed data
from returns filed in 2005, the latest year for which data are available.
In 2008, estates valued over $2.0 million must file an estate tax return. The applicable credit,
which is identical to the filing threshold, effectively exempts from taxation the portion of the

3 For a history of the estate and gift tax as well as a detailed explanation of current law, see the following CRS reports
by John R. Luckey: CRS Report 95-416, Federal Estate, Gift, and Generation-Skipping Taxes: A Description of
Current Law, and CRS Report 95-444, A History of Federal Estate, Gift, and Generation-Skipping Taxes.





estate that falls below the filing threshold. (The filing threshold is lower, however, if gifts have
already been made.) Table A-1 in the appendix reports the current filing requirement and the
unified credit equivalent for 2004 through 2011.
The gross estate value, which was $211.5 billion for returns filed in 2006, is the total value of all
property and assets owned by decedents. Table A-2 in the appendix provides the gross estate
value for returns filed in 2006 by wealth category. The data represent the returns filed in 2006, not
the decedents in that year. Thus, a portion of the returns filed in 2006 are from estates valued in
years before 2006.
Deductions from the estate reduce the taxable portion of the gross estate and in turn the number
of taxable returns. In 2006, $98.3 billion was deducted from estates. The most valuable deduction
is for bequests to a surviving spouse, $65.8 billion; the most prevalent (though smallest reported)
deduction is for funeral expenses, $415.1 million. Appendix Table A-3 lists the deductions in
greater detail for returns filed in 2006. Beginning in 2005, estates may deduct state estate taxes
paid. Before 2005, taxpayers received a federal credit for state death taxes paid. That credit was
phased out incrementally from 2002 through 2004.
After subtracting allowable deductions, the remainder of the estate is the taxable estate. Taxable
estate value was $113.6 billion in 2006. Adjusted taxable gifts are then added to the taxable estate
to arrive upon the adjusted taxable estate. An individual is allowed to exclude $12,000 in gifts per
year per donee from taxable gifts. Thus, only the amount exceeding the $12,000 limit is added
back to the taxable estate. Only 10,997 returns filed in 2006 included taxable gifts, adding
approximately $7.7 billion to the total estate value. Thus, adjusted taxable estates were worth
$121.3 billion in 2006. Generally, the adjusted taxable estate represents the base of estate tax.
After establishing the value of the taxable estate, the executor calculates the tentative estate tax 4
due. The tax due is tentative because the executor has not redeemed the applicable credit 5
amount. As noted earlier, the credit for state estate and inheritance taxes was repealed and
replaced with a deduction beginning in 2005.
The remaining steps in calculating the estate and gift tax are most easily exhibited through
numerical example. To accomplish this, we first assume a decedent, who dies in 2008, has an

4 26 I.R.C. 2001(c).
5 The federal credit for state death taxes paid was repealed beginning in 2005. See Table A-4 in the appendix for the
old credit for state death taxes paid schedule.





estate worth $5 million and leaves $2 million to his wife and contributes $400,000 to a charitable
organization. We also assume the decedent has not made any taxable gifts leaving $2.6 million in
his estate after deductions. This simple example is exhibited below.
Table 1. Numerical Example
(2008 rules)
Gross Estate Value $5,000,000
—Less: hypothetical marital deduction $2,000,000
—Less: hypothetical charitable contribution deduction $400,000
Taxable Estate $2,600,000
The taxable estate is valued at $2.6 million after the allowable deductions have been subtracted 6
from the gross estate value. The tax is applied to the $2.6 million in increments of estate value as
provided for in the tax code. For example, the first increment of $10,000 is taxed at 18%, the
second increment of $10,000 is taxed at 20%, the third increment of $20,000 is taxed at 22%, etc.
This process continues until the entire $2.6 million is taxed. The last increment of estate value,
that from $1.5 million to $2.6 million, is taxed at a 45% rate. Thus, even though this estate is in
the 45% bracket, only a portion ($1.1 million) of the estate is taxed at the 45% rate.
In 2006, the aggregate tentative estate tax after deductions and before credits was $50.3 billion.
Returning to our example, the $2.6 million taxable estate yields a tentative estate tax of
$1,050,800. Recall, however, we have not yet considered the “applicable credit.”
For decedents dying in 2008, the applicable credit is $780,800, which leaves an estate tax due in
our example of $270,000. The applicable credit reduced the tentative estate tax by $27.4 billion in

2006.


The state death tax credit reduced the federal estate tax due by $261.5 million in 2006.7 This tax
credit is determined by yet another tax rate schedule. The taxable estate value, which is $2.6
million in our example, is reduced by a standard exemption of $60,000 and the credit rate
schedule applies to the remainder. EGTRRA reduces and eventually repeals the credit for state
death taxes. In 2004, the credit was 25% of what the credit would have been before EGTRRA. In
2005, the credit was repealed and estates were allowed to deduct state death taxes paid. Table A-5
of the appendix reproduces the now-repealed credit schedule for state death taxes. For our

6 We have dropped the modifieradjusted from taxable estate for the benefit of the reader. The taxable estate and the
adjusted taxable estate are identical in the absence of taxable gifts.
7 The data are from those estates that filed in 2006, thus some estates followed the 2004 rules which still included the
credit for state death taxes.





hypothetical estate filed in 2008, the credit is not available and thus state death taxes would be
deductible. In many states, however, the state estate tax is repealed along with the federal credit.
The net estate tax due was $24.7 billion in 2006.8 This is the final step for the estate executor.
After all exemptions, deductions, and credits, the $5 million dollar estate we began with must
now remit $270,000 to the federal government.
All of the steps described above are included in Table 2. Also, an estimate of the average estate
tax rate is presented in the bottom row. The federal rate is calculated as the federal estate tax due
divided by the gross estate value.
Table 2. Numerical Example Continued with Taxes and Credits
(2008 rules)
Gross Estate Value $5,000,000
—Less: hypothetical marital deduction $2,000,000
—Less: hypothetical charitable contribution deduction $400,000
Taxable Estate $2,600,000
Tentative Estate Tax (from the rate schedule) $1,050,800
—Less: Applicable Credit Amount (in 2007) $780,800
Net Federal Estate Tax $270,000
Average Effective Federal Estate Tax Rate 5.40%
There are primarily two special rules for family owned farms and businesses. The first special
rule (26 I.R.C. 6166) allows family owned farm and business estates to pay the tax in installments
over a maximum of 10 years after a deferment of up to five years. The farm or business must
comprise at least 35% of the adjusted gross estate value to qualify for the installment method. A
portion of the deferred estate tax is assessed an annual 2% interest charge.
The second special rule (26 I.R.C. 2032A) allows family farms and businesses that meet certain
requirements to value their land as currently used rather than at fair market value. To avoid a
recapture tax, heirs must continue to use the land as designated in the special use notice for at
least 10 years following the transfer. The market value can be reduced by a maximum $750,000
in 1998. After 1998, the maximum is indexed for inflation, rounded to the next lowest multiple of
$10,000. In 2007, the maximum was $940,000.

8 This is slightly greater than the tentative estate tax less credits because of rounding.





Generally, the generation skipping transfer (GST) tax is levied on transfers from the decedent to
grandchildren. The tax includes a $2,000,000 exemption per donor in 2008 that is pegged to the
general estate tax exclusion. Married couples are allowed to “split” their gifts for an effective
exemption of $3,000,000. The rate of tax is the highest estate and gift tax rate or 45% in 2008
These transfers are also subject to applicable estate and gift taxes. The GST exemption rises to
$3.5 million in 2009. Very few estates pay a generation skipping transfer tax because the high rate
of tax discourages this type of bequest.

As noted in the “Introduction,” the principal arguments surrounding the estate and gift tax are
associated with the desirability of reducing the concentration of wealth and income through the
tax and the possible adverse effect of the tax on savings behavior and family businesses. There
are a number of other issues of fairness or efficiency associated with particular aspects of the tax
(e.g. marital deductions, charitable deductions, effects on small businesses, interaction with
capital gains taxes) , and the possible contribution to tax complexity. These issues are addressed
in this section.
Distributional effects concern both vertical equity (how high income individuals are affected
relative to low income individuals) and horizontal equity (how individuals in equal circumstances
are differentially affected). Note that economic analysis cannot be used to determine the optimal
degree of distribution across income and wealth (vertical equity).
The estate tax is the most progressive of any of the federal taxes; out of the approximately 2.4 9
million deaths in 2004, only 1.3% of estates paid any estate tax. This percentage can be
contrasted with the income tax where most families and single individuals file tax returns and
about 70% of those returns owe tax. In addition, out of the 1.3% of decedents whose estates pay
tax, about 70% of these had gross estates valued between $1 million and $2.5 million in 2004,
which are the smallest (based on gross estate value) taxable estates.
Evidence suggests that the average effective tax rate rises with the size of the estate except for the
highest tax rate bracket, as shown in Table 3 [columns (f) and (g)]. Column (f) reports 2006
effective tax rates for the decedent before the credit for state death taxes and column (g) shows
the actual amount paid to the federal government after all credits. Estates valued at less than the
exemption amount, of course, pay no taxes and the tax rate rises and then falls with the very
largest estates, despite the fact that the rates are graduated.

9 Mortality data for 2004 is the latest year available.





Columns (b), (c), and (d) show the deductions from the estate as a percentage of gross estate
value. Charitable deductions are the primary reason for the lower tax rate in the highest levels of
the estate tax. The charitable deduction accounts for 8.3% of estates on average but 17.8% in the
highest wealth bracket. The deduction for bequests left to spouse also rises as a portion of the
gross estate as estate size increases. The progressivity of the estate tax for the estates valued at
less than $10 million is the result of the unified credit and the graduated rate structure.
The data in Table 3 may actually overstate the amount of rate progression in the estate tax. Tax
planning techniques, such as gift tax exclusions or valuation discounts, reduce the size of the
gross estate and are more common with larger estates. These techniques reduce the size of the
estate but do not appear in the IRS data, thus, the effective tax rates may be overstated for larger
estates.
Despite the lack of progressivity through all of the estate size brackets, the principal point for
distributional purposes is that the estate and gift tax is confined to the wealthiest of decedents and
to a tiny share of the population. For example, estates over $5 million accounted for 18.8% of
taxable estates, but accounted for 71.9% of estate tax revenues in 2006. Thus, to the extent that
concentration of income and wealth are viewed as undesirable, the estate tax plays some role,
albeit small—because few pay the tax—in increasing income and wealth equality.
Note also an effect that contradicts some claims made by opponents of the tax. The Carnegie 10
conjecture suggests that large inheritances reduce labor effort by heirs. Thus, the estate tax,
which reduces inheritances, could increase output and economic growth because heirs work more
(increase their labor supply) if their inheritance is reduced. Although, for very large inheritances,
the effect of one individual on the labor supply may be small relative to the effect on saving.
Table 3. Estate Tax Deductions and Burdens, 2006
Percent of Gross Estate Tax as a Percent of Net Estatea Size of Gross
Estate Bequests to Before After Unified After All
($ millions) Expenses Spouse Charity Credit Credit Creditsb
(a) (b) (c) (d) (e) (f) (g)
2.0-3.5 6.09% 24.02% 4.44% 27.73% 4.14% 7.50%
3.5-5.0 6.04% 30.22% 4.55% 26.60% 11.85% 13.11%
5.0-10.0 5.24% 36.02% 6.05% 24.51% 15.58% 16.08%
10.0-20.0 5.76% 38.45% 7.80% 23.20% 18.72% 18.68%
over 20.0 5.26% 40.04% 17.83% 17.68% 16.65% 16.43%
Total 5.62% 31.13% 8.32% 26.60% 10.72% 12.35%
Source: CRS calculations from Statistics of Income, Estate Tax Returns Filed in 2006, IRS, SOI unpublished data,
November 2007.
a. Net estate is estate value less expenses. Expenses include funeral expenses, attorney’s fees, executors’
commissions, other expenses/losses, and debts and mortgages.

10 For more see Douglas Holtz-Eakin, David Joulfaian, and Harvey Rosen, “The Carnegie Conjecture: Some Empirical
Evidence,Quarterly Journal of Economics, v. 108, May 1993, pp. 413-435.





b. This includes any gift taxes that are owed by an estate, which could increase the total taxes owed by an
estate.
Estate and gift taxes can affect similar individuals differentially for a variety of reasons. Special
provisions for farmers and family businesses (discussed subsequently) can cause families with the
same amount of wealth to be taxed differentially. The availability and differential use of
avoidance techniques (also discussed subsequently) can lead to different tax burdens for the same
amount of wealth. Moreover, individuals who accumulate similar amounts of wealth may pay
differential taxes depending on how long they live.
Many people presume that the estate tax reduces savings, since the estate and gift tax, like a
capital income tax, applies to wealth. It may appear “obvious” that a tax on wealth would reduce
wealth. However, taxes on capital income do not necessarily reduce savings. This ambiguous
result arises from the opposing forces of an income and substitution effect. An investment is made
to provide future consumption; if the rate of return rises because a tax is cut, more consumption
might be shifted from the present to the future (the substitution effect). This effect, in isolation,
would increase saving.
However, the tax savings also increases the return earned on investment and allows higher
consumption both today and in the future. This effect is called an income effect, and it tends to
reduce saving. Its effect is most pronounced when the savings is for a fixed target (such as a fund
for college tuition or a target bequest to an heir). Thus, saving for precautionary reasons (as a
hedge against bad events) is less likely to increase when the rate of return rises than saving for
retirement. Empirical evidence on savings responses, while difficult to obtain, suggests a small
effect of uncertain sign (i.e. either positive or negative). Current events certainly suggest that
savings fall when the rate of return rises: as returns on stocks have increased dramatically, the
savings rate has plunged.
The same points can generally be made about a tax on estates and gifts, although some analysts
suspect that an estate tax, to be paid at a distant date in the future, would be less likely to have an
effect (in either direction) than income taxes being paid currently. A reduction in estate taxes
makes a larger net bequest possible, reducing the price of the bequest in terms of forgone
consumption. This substitution effect would cause savings to increase. At the same time, a
reduction in estate taxes causes the net estate to be larger, allowing a larger net bequest to be
made with a smaller amount of savings (the income effect). Again, the latter effect is most
pronounced when there is a target net bequest; a smaller gross bequest can be left (and less
savings required on the part of the decedent) to achieve the net target.
Unfortunately, virtually no empirical evidence about the effect of estate and gift taxes exists, in
part because these taxes have been viewed as small and relatively unimportant by most
researchers and in part because there are tremendous difficulties in trying to link an estate and gift
tax which occurs at the end of a lifetime to annual savings behavior. But a reasonable expectation
is that the effects of cutting the estate and gift tax on savings would not be large and would not
even necessarily be positive.





Of course, the effect on national saving depends on the use to which tax revenues are put. If
revenues are used to decrease the national debt, they become part of government saving, and it is
more likely that cutting estate and gift taxes would reduce saving by decreasing government
saving, since there may be little or no effect on private saving. If they are used for government
spending on consumption programs, or transfers that are primarily used for consumption, then it
is less likely that cutting estate and gift taxes would reduce saving because the estate tax cut
would be financed out of decreased consumption (rather than decreased saving). In this case,
reducing the tax would probably have a small effect on national saving, since the evidence
suggests a small effect on private saving. A similar effect would occur if tax revenues are held
constant and the alternative tax primarily reduced consumption.
Actually, the estate and gift tax is, in some ways, more complicated to assess than a tax on capital
income or wealth. There are a variety of possible motives for leaving bequests, which are likely to
cause savings to respond differently to the estate tax. In addition, there are consequences for the
heirs which may affect their savings.
Several of these alternative motives and their consequences are outlined by Gale and Perozek.11
Motives for leaving bequests include (1) altruism: individuals want to increase the welfare of
their children and other descendants because they care about them; (2) accident: individuals do
not intentionally save to leave a bequest but as a fund to cover unexpected costs or the costs of
living longer than expected (thus, bequests are left by accident and are in the nature of
precautionary savings); (3) exchange: parents promise to leave bequests to their children in
exchange for services (visiting, looking after parents when they are sick); and (4) joy of giving:
individuals get pleasure directly from giving, with the pleasure depending on the size of the
estate. To Gale and Perozek’s classifications we might add satiation: when individuals have so
much wealth that any consumption desire can be met.
The theoretical effects of these alternative theories on decedents and heirs are summarized in
Table 4. A discussion of each follows in the text, but it is interesting to see that there is a
tendency for estate taxes to increase saving, not decrease it. This effect occurs in part because
there are “double” income effects that discourage consumption, acting on both the decedent and
the heir.
When giving is motivated by altruism, the effect of the tax is ambiguous, as might not be
surprising given the discussion of income and substitution effects. The effects on the parents are
ambiguous, while the windfall receipt of an inheritance tends to reduce the need to save by the
children. That is, the estate tax reduces the inheritances and thus increases saving by heirs. The
outcomes are also partly dependent on whether children think they can elicit a larger inheritance
by squandering their own money (which causes them to save even less) and whether the parent
sees this problem and responds to it in a way that forestalls it. Interestingly, some parents might
respond by spending a lot of their assets before death to induce their children to be more
responsible and save more. The cost of doing this is the reduction in welfare of their children
from the smaller bequest as compared with the parent’s benefit from consumption. The estate tax

11 William G. Gale and Maria G. Perozek. Do Estate Taxes Reduce Savings? April 2000. Presented at a Conference on
Estate and Gift Taxes sponsored by the Office of Tax Policy Research, University of Michigan, and the Brookings
Institution, May 4-5, 2000.





actually makes the cost of using this method smaller (in terms of reduced bequests for each dollar
spent), and causes the parents to consume more. While these motivations and actions of parent
and child can become complex, this theory leaves us with an ambiguous effect on savings.
In the second case, where bequests are left because parents die before they have exhausted their
resources, the estate tax has no effect on the saving of the parents. Indeed, the parents are not
really concerned about the estate tax since it has no effect on the reason they are accumulating
assets. If they need the assets because they live too long or become ill, no tax will be paid.
Bequests are a windfall to children, in this case, and tend to increase their consumption. Thus,
taxing bequests, because it reduces this windfall, reduces their consumption and promotes
savings. If the revenue from the estate tax is saved by the government, national saving rises. (If
the revenue is spent on consumption, there is no effect on savings.) Thus, in this case, the estate
tax reduces private consumption and repealing it, reducing the surplus, would increase
consumption (reduce savings).
In the third case, parents are basically paying for children’s services with bequests and the estate
tax becomes like a tax on products: the price for their children’s attention has increased. Not
surprisingly, the savings and size of bequest by the parents depends on how responsive they are to
these price changes. If the demand is less responsive to price changes (price inelastic), parents
will save and bequeath more to make up for the tax to be sure of receiving their children’s
services, but if there are close substitutes they might save less, bequeath less, and purchase
alternatives (e.g. nursing home care). In this model, the child’s saving is not affected, since the
bequest is payment for forgone wages (or leisure).
Table 4. Theoretical Effect of Estate Tax on Saving, By Bequest Motive
Bequest Motive Effect on Decedent Saving Effect on Heir Saving
Altruism Ambiguous Increases
Accidental None Increases
Exchange Ambiguous None
Joy of Giving Ambiguous Increases
Satiation None Increases or None
A fourth motive is called the “joy-of-giving” motive, where individuals simply enjoy leaving a
bequest. If the parent focuses on the before-tax bequest, the estate tax will have no effect on his or
her behavior, but will reduce the inheritance and theoretically increase the saving of children.
Thus, repealing the estate tax would reduce private saving. If the parent focuses on the after-tax
bequest, the effect on saving is ambiguous (again, due to income and substitution effects).





Some families may be so wealthy that they can satisfy all of their consumption needs without
feeling any constraints and their wealth accumulation may be a (large) residual. In this case, as
well, the estate tax would have no effect on saving of the donor, and perhaps little effect on the
donee as well.
Evidence for these motives is not clear but this analysis does suggest that there are many
circumstances in which a repeal of the estate tax would reduce savings, not increase it. Virtually
no work has been done to estimate the effect of estate taxes on accumulation of assets. A
preliminary analysis of estate tax data by Kopczuk and Slemrod found some limited evidence of a
negative effect on savings, but this effect was not robust (i.e. did not persist with changes in data 12
sets or specification). This effect was relatively small in any case and the authors stress the
many limitations of their results. In particular, their analysis cannot distinguish between the
reduction of estates due to savings responses and those due to tax avoidance techniques.
Given the paucity of empirical evidence on the issue, the evidence on savings responses in
general, and the theory outlined above, it appears difficult to argue for repeal of the estate tax to
increase private saving. Even if the responsiveness to the estate and gift tax is as large as the
largest empirical estimates of interest elasticities, the effect on savings and output would be 13
negligible and more than offset by public dissaving. Indeed, if the only objective were increased
savings, it would probably be more effective to simply keep the estate and gift tax and use the
proceeds to reduce the national debt.
Much attention been focused on the effect of the estate and gift tax on family farms and
businesses and there is a perception that the estate tax is a significant burden on these businesses.
Typically, family farm and business owners hold significant wealth in business and farm assets as
well as other assets such as stocks, bonds and cash. Because many business owners are relatively
well off and the estate and gift tax is a progressive tax, the probability of a farm or small business 14
owner encountering tax liability is greater than for other decedents.

12 Wojciech Kopczuk and Joel Slemrod, “The Impact of the Estate Tax on the Wealth Accumulation and Avoidance
Behavior of Donors, in William G. Gale, James R. Hines Jr., and Joel B. Slemrod, eds., Rethinking Estate and Gift
Taxation, pp. 299-343. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 2001.
13 Interest elasticities have been estimated at no higher than 0.4; that is, a one percent increase in the rate of return
would increase savings by 0.4%. Ignoring the effect on the deficit or assuming the revenue loss is made up by some
other tax or spending program that has no effect on private savings, this amount is about 40% of the revenue cost, so
that savings might initially increase by about $12 billion. Output would rise by this increase multiplied by the interest
rate, or about $1 billion (or, 1/100 of 1% of output). In the long run, savings would accumulate, and national income
might eventually increase by about one tenth of 1%. (This calculation is based on the following: the current revenue
cost of $28 billion accounts for about 1.4% of capital income of approximately 25% of Net National Product; at an
elasticity of 0.4, a 1.4% increase in income would lead to a 0.56 % increase in the capital stock and multiplying by the
capital share of income (0.25) would lead to an approximate 0.14 increase in the capital stock.)
14 See CRS Report RL33070, Estate Taxes and Family Businesses: Economic Issues, by Jane G. Gravelle and Steven
Maguire.





Opponents of the estate and gift tax suggest that a family business or farm may in fact have to sell
assets, often at a discounted price, to pay the tax. In his 1997 testimony, Bruce Bartlett from the
National Center for Policy Analysis, stated that
...according to a survey, 51% of businesses would have difficulty surviving in the event of
principal owner’s death and 14% said it would be impossible for them to survive. Only 10%
said the estate tax would have no effect; 30% said they would have to sell the family 15
business, and 41% would have to borrow against equity.
Are the data from this survey representative of the country as a whole? And, what are the policy
issues associated with this effect? In response to the above testimony, there are two questions to
explore. One, is repeal of the estate and gift tax efficiently targeted to relieve farms and small
businesses? And two, of the farmer and small business decedents, how many actually encounter
estate tax liability?
Congress has incorporated into tax law provisions, outlined earlier, that address and reduce the
negative consequences of the estate tax on farms and small businesses. These laws are targeted to
benefit only farm and small business heirs. In contrast, proposals to repeal the estate and gift tax
entirely are poorly targeted to farms and small businesses.
Of the 22,798 taxable returns filed in 2006, 1,442 (6.3%) included farm assets. Additionally, no 16
more than 9,837 (43.2%) returns included “business assets” in the estate. (Note that some
returns are double counted). Together, farm and business owners, by our definition, represent 17
approximately 49.5% of all taxable estate tax returns.
However, this estimate is dramatically overstated, even aside from the likelihood of double
counting. The estimate for farms assumes any estate with a farm asset is a farm return thus
including part-time farmers or those who may own farm land not directly farmed. The estimate
for business assets may include many returns that include small interests (particularly for
corporate stock and partnerships). Treasury data for 1998 indicated that farm estates where farm
assets accounted for at least half of the gross estate accounted for 1.4% of taxable estates, while
returns with closely held stock, non-corporate business or partnership assets equal to half of the
gross estate accounted for 1.6%. The same data indicated that farm real estate and other farm
assets in these returns accounted for 0.6% of the gross value of estates. Similarly estates with half
of the assets representing business assets accounted for 4.1% of estates’ gross values. Thus, it is
clear that if the main motive for repealing the estate tax or reducing rates across-the-board were to
assist farms and small businesses, most of the revenue loss would accrue to those outside the
target group.

15 Statement before the Subcommittee on Tax, Finance, and Exports, Committee on Small Business, June 12, 1997.
16 A return is classified as a business return if at least one of the following assets is in the estate: closely held stock,
limited partnerships, real estate partnership, other non-corporate business assets. Counting the same estate more than
once is likely which significantly overstates the number of business estate tax returns.
17 See CRS Report RS20593, Asset Distribution of Taxable Estates: An Analysis, by Steven Maguire.





The more difficult question to answer is how many decedent farmers and small family business
owners pay the tax. The first step in answering this question is to estimate the number of farmers
and business owners (or those with farm and business assets) who die in any given year. We
chose 2003 as our base year.
About 2.3 million people 25 and over died in the United States in 2004.18 Some portion were farm
and business owners. To estimate the number of those who died that were farm or business
owners, we assume that the distribution of income tax filers roughly approximates the distribution
of deaths in any given year. Or, the portion of farm individual income tax returns to total income
tax returns in 2004 approximates the number farm deaths to total deaths. The same logic is used
to approximate the number of business owner deaths. (Note that farmers tend to be older than
other occupational groups and have somewhat higher death rates, which may slightly overstate
our estimates of the share of farmer estates with tax).
In 2004, there were 132.2 million individual income tax returns filed; about 2 million were
classified as farm returns and 20.3 million included business income or loss. These returns
represent 1.5% and 15.3% of all returns respectively. If the profile of individual income tax return
filers is similar to the profile of decedents, this implies approximately 35,267 farmers and 19

356,245 business owners died in 2004.


Recall that the estate tax return data include 1,442 taxable returns with farm assets and 9,837
taxable returns we classify as business returns. Dividing these two numbers by the estimated
number of deaths for each vocation yields an taxable estate tax return rate of 4.1% for farm owner
decedents and 2.8% for business owner decedents. Thus, one can conclude that most farmers and
business owners are unlikely to encounter estate tax liability.
Liquidity constraints or the inability of farms and small business to meet their tax liability with
cash, may not be widespread. A CBO analysis of 1999 and 2000 estate tax data indicated that
between 8% and 12% of estates with farm assets owed estate taxes greater than their liquid assets,
while returns with closely held stock, compared to 5% of estates that owed estate taxes. Similarly,
CBO found that nearly one-third of small businesses that claim the qualified family-owned 20
business-interest deduction owe estate taxes greater than their liquid assets.
Further, estimates using 1992 data suggest that 41% of business owners could pay estate and gift
taxes solely out of narrowly defined liquid assets (insurance proceeds, cash and bank accounts); if
stocks (equities) were included in a business’s liquid assets, an estimated 54% could cover their 21
estate and gift tax liability; if bonds are included an estimated 58% could cover their tax.

18 Mortality data for 2004 is the latest year available.
19 The percentages are multiplied by the 2,374,781 deaths of those 25 years old and over. If the age were higher then
the pool of decedents would be smaller and the percentage that paid estate taxes incrementally higher.
20 U.S. Congressional Budget Office. Effects of the Federal Estate Tax on Farms and Small Businesses. July 2005.
21 Holtz-Eakin, Douglas, John W. Philips, and Harvey S. Rosen, “Estate Taxes, Life Insurance, and Small Business,”
Review of Economics and Statistics, v83 n1, 2001.





These estimates suggest that only 3% to 4% of family farms and businesses would potentially be
at risk even without accounting for the special exemptions; the special exemption suggests a 22
much smaller number would be at risk. If one included other non-business assets that are either
not included in these estimates through lack of data (such as pensions) or nonfinancial assets
(such as real estate) the estimate would be even higher. For many businesses a partial sale of
assets (e.g. a portion of farm land) might be made or business assets could be used as security for
loans to pay the tax. Finally, some estates may wish to liquidate the business because no heir
wishes to continue it. Given these studies and analysis, it appears that only a tiny fraction, almost
certainly no more than a percent or so, of heirs of business owners and farmers would be at risk of
being forced to liquidate the family business to pay estate and gift taxes.
One of the most important deductions from the estate tax is the unlimited marital deduction,
which accounted for 31.1% of the gross value of all estates, and over 40% for larger estates (see
Table 3; larger estates may be more likely to reflect the death of the first spouse). An individual
can leave his or her entire estate to a surviving spouse without paying any tax and getting step-up
in basis (which permits no tax on accrued gains). The arguments for an unlimited marital
deduction are obvious: since spouses tend to be relatively close in age, taxing wealth transferred
between spouses amounts to a “double tax” in a generation and also discourages the adequate
provision for the surviving spouse (although this latter objective could be met with a large, but
not necessarily unlimited, marital deduction). (There is, however, a partial credit for prior
transfers within a decade which could mitigate this double taxation within a generation.)
Moreover, without an exclusion for assets transferred to the spouse, a substantial amount of
planning early in the married couple’s life (e.g. allowing for joint ownership of assets) could
make a substantial difference in the estate tax liability.
Nevertheless, the unlimited marital deduction causes a certain amount of distortion. If a spouse
leaves all assets to the surviving spouse, he or she forgoes the unified credit, equivalent to an
exclusion that is currently $2.0 million and will eventually reach $3.5 million in 2009. In
addition, because the estate tax is graduated, leaving all assets to a spouse can cause the couple to
lose the advantage of going through the lower rate brackets twice. A very wealthy donor would
leave enough to children (or to the ultimate beneficiary after the second spouse’s death) to cover
the exemption and to go through all of the rate brackets; then when the second spouse dies,
another exemption and another “walk through the rate brackets” will be available. Donors can try
to avoid the loss of these benefits and still provide for the surviving spouse by setting up trusts to
allow lifetime income to the spouse and perhaps provide for invasion of the corpus for
emergencies. These methods, of course, require pre-planning and may not be perfect substitutes
for simply leaving assets to the surviving spouse, who would not have complete control.
Under other circumstances, the unlimited marital deduction can cause a decedent to leave more
wealth to his or her spouse than would otherwise be preferable. For example, a decedent with
children from a previous marriage might like to leave more assets to the children but the
unlimited marital deduction may make it more attractive to leave assets to a spouse. One way of
dealing with this problem is to leave a lifetime interest to the spouse and direct the disposal of the
corpus of the trust to children. Indeed, the tax law facilitates this approach by allowing a trust

22 Of course, if all heirs do not wish to continue ownership in the family business, these liquid assets might need to be
used to buy them out; that, however, is a choice made by the heirs and not a forced sale.





called a Qualified Terminable Interest Property (QTIP) trust. Nevertheless, this approach also
requires planning and is not a perfect substitute for directly leaving assets to children (particularly
if the spouse has a long prospective life).
The point is that these provisions, whether deemed desirable or undesirable, distort the choices of
a decedent and cause more resources to be devoted to estate planning than would otherwise be the
case.
One reason frequently cited by tax analysts for retaining an estate tax is that the tax acts as a
back-up for a source of leakage in the individual income tax—the failure to tax capital gains
passed on at death. Normally, a capital gains tax applies on the difference between the sales price
of an asset and the cost of acquiring it (this cost is referred to as the basis). Under current law,
accumulated capital gains on an asset held until death will never be subject to the capital gains tax
because the heirs will treat the market value at time of death (rather than original cost) as their
basis. Assuming market values are estimated correctly, if heirs immediately sold these assets, no
tax would be due. This treatment is referred to as “step-up in basis.” It is estimated that 36% or 23
more of gains escape taxes through step-up.
The estate and gift tax is not a carefully designed back-up for the capital gains tax. It allows no
deduction for original cost basis, it has large exemptions which may exclude much of capital
gains from the tax in any case (including the unlimited marital deduction), and the tax rates vary
from those that would be imposed on capital gains if realized. In particular, estate tax rates can be
much larger than those imposed on capital gains (the current capital gains tax is capped at 20%,
while the maximum marginal estate tax rate is 45%).
If the capital gains tax were the primary reason for retaining an estate and gift tax, then the tax
could be restructured to impose capital gains taxes on a constructive realization basis.
Alternatively, one could adopt a carry-over of basis, so that the basis remained the original cost,
although this proposal could still allow an indefinite deferral of gain.
Owner occupied housing and life insurance also escape income taxes on capital gains accrued
through inside build-up (for the most part). Owner-occupied housing also escapes income tax on
implicit rental income. There are practical economic and administrative reasons for some of these
tax rules. It is administratively difficult to tax implicit rental income and taxing capital gains
could potentially impede labor mobility. There are other assets as well that escape the income tax
(such as tax exempt bonds). The estate and gift tax could also be seen as a backstop for these
lapses in the individual income tax.

23 See Poterba, James M. and Scott Weisbenner,The Distributional Burden of Taxing Estates and Unrealized capital
Gains at the Time of Death,National Bureau of Economic Research, no. 7811, July 2000, p. 36.





One group that benefits from the presence of an estate and gift tax is the non-profit sector, since
charitable contributions can be given or bequeathed without paying tax. As shown in Table 3,
estates that filed returns in 2006 donated 8.3% of total assets to charities; estates that occupy the
highest wealth class ($20 million or greater) donated 17.8% of total assets to charity. Although
one recent study found that charitable bequests are very responsive to the estate tax, and indeed
that the charitable deduction is “target efficient” in the sense that it induces more charitable
contributions than it loses in revenue, other studies have found a variety of responses, both small 24
and large. One problem with these types of studies is the difficulty in separating wealth and
price effects.
An individual would have even greater tax benefits if charitable contributions were made during
the lifetime, since they are deductible for purposes of the income tax, thereby reducing not only
income tax but also, because the eventual estate is reduced, the estate tax as well. On the other
hand, under the income tax charitable gifts are limited to 50% of income (30% for private
foundations) and there are also restrictions on the ability to deduct appreciated property at full
value. Despite this effect, a significant amount of charitable giving occurs through bequests and
one study estimated that total charitable giving through bequests would fall by 12% if the estate 2526
tax were eliminated. This reduction is, however, less than 1% of total charitable contributions.
Charitable deductions play a role in some estate planning techniques described in the next
section. In addition, some charitable deductions allow considerable retention of control by the
heirs, as in the case of private foundations. Unlike the case of the income tax, there are no special
restrictions on bequests to private foundations. (Under the income tax system, deductibility as a
percent of income is more limited for gifts to foundations; there are also more limitations on gifts
of appreciated property to foundations).
A number of tax planning and tax avoidance techniques take advantage of the annual gift
exclusion, the charitable deduction, the unlimited marital deduction, and issues of valuation.
Because choices made with respect to these techniques can affect total tax liability, these planning
techniques complicate compliance on the part of the taxpayer and administration on the part of
the IRS. They may also induce individuals to arrange their affairs in ways that would not
otherwise be desirable, resulting in distortions of economic behavior.
The most straightforward method of reducing estate and gift taxes is to transfer assets as gifts
during the lifetime (inter-vivos transfers) rather than bequests. Gifts are generally subject to lower
taxes for two reasons. First, assets can be transferred without affecting the unified credit because
of the $12,000 annual exclusion. The exclusion was designed to permit gifts (such as wedding
and Christmas presents) without involving the complication of the gift tax. This annual exclusion

24 See David Joulfaian, “Estate Taxes and Charitable Bequests by the Wealth,” National Tax Journal v53 n3,
November 2000. This paper contains a review of the econometric literature on the charitable response. Note that, in
general, a tax incentive induces more spending than it loses in revenue when the elasticity (the percentage change in
spending divided by the percentage change in taxes) is greater than one.
25 Ibid.
26 Bruce Bartlett, Misplaced Fears for Generosity, Washington Times, June 26, 2000, p. A16.





can, however, allow very large lifetime gifts. For example, a couple with two children, who are
both married, could make $96,000 of tax-free gifts per year (each spouse could give $12,000 to
each child and the child’s spouse). Over 10 years, $960,000 could be transferred tax free (and
without reducing the lifetime credit). Moreover, the estate is further reduced by the appreciation
on these assets.
The effective gift tax is also lower than the estate tax because it is imposed on a tax-exclusive
basis rather than a tax-inclusive basis. For example, if the tax rate is 45%, a taxable gift (beyond
the $12,000 limit) of $100,000 can be given with a $45,000 gift tax, for an out-of-pocket total
cost to the decedent of $145,000. However, if the transfer were made at death, the estate tax on
the total outlay of $145,000 would be 45% of the total, or $65,250. Despite these significant 27
advantages, especially from the annual exclusion, relatively little inter-vivos giving occurs.
There are a number of possible reasons for this failure to take advantage of the gift exclusion, and
one is that the donee does not wish to relinquish economic control or perhaps provide assets to
children before they are deemed to have sufficient maturity to handle them. There are certain trust
and other devices that have been developed to allow some control to be maintained while 28
utilizing the annual gift tax exclusion. The annual gift exclusion can also be used to shift the
ownership of insurance policies away from the person whose life is insured and out of the gross
estate.
One particular method that allows a potentially large amount of estate tax avoidance is a
Crummey trust. Normally, gifts placed in a trust are not eligible for the $12,000 exclusion, unless
the trust allows a present interest by the beneficiary. The courts have held that contributions to a
trust that allows the beneficiary withdrawal rights, even if the individual is a minor, and even if
withdrawal rights are available for only a brief period (e.g. 15 or 30 days), can be treated as gifts
eligible for the annual exclusion. This rule has been used to remove insurance assets from an
estate (by placing them in a trust and using the annual $12,000 gift exclusion to pay the premiums
without incurring tax). Under the Crummey trust, a large number of individuals (who may be
children or other relatives of the primary beneficiaries) can be given the right (a right not usually
exercised) to withdraw up to $12,000 over the limited time period. (Under lapse of power rules,
however, this amount is sometimes limited to $6,000). All of these individuals are not necessarily
primary beneficiaries of the trust but they expand the gift exclusion aggregate. In one case, a 29
Crummey trust with 35 donees was reported.
There is, however, one disadvantage of inter vivos gifts: these gifts do not benefit from the step-
up in basis at death that allows capital gains to go unrecognized, so that very wealthy families
with assets with large unrealized gains might prefer bequests (at least after the annual exclusion is 30
used up).

27 See James Poterba. “Estate and Gift Taxes and Incentives for Inter Vivos Giving in the United States,” Journal of
Public Economics v79 n1, Jan. 2001. Even at high income levels, Poterba found that only about 45% of households
take advantage of lifetime giving. He also found that those with illiquid assets (such as family businesses) and those
with large unrealized capital gains are less likely to make inter-vivos gifts.
28 For a more complete discussion of this and other techniques, see Richard Schmalbeck,Avoiding Wealth Transfer
Taxes,” in William G. Gale, James R. Hines Jr., and Joel B. Slemrod, eds., Rethinking Estate and Gift Taxation, pp.
113-163. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 2001. and Charles Davenport and Jay Soled. Enlivening the
Death-Tax Death-Talk. Tax Notes, July 26, 1999, pp. 591-629.
29 See Davenport and Soled, op cit.
30 See David Joulfaian, Choosing Between Gifts and Bequests: How Taxes Affect the Timing of Wealth Transfers,
National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper no. 11025, Jan. 2005.





Individuals can also avoid taxes by skipping generations; although there is a generation skipping
tax, there are large exemptions from the tax ($2.0 million per decedent in 2008, the same as the
general estate tax exemption amount). Generation skipping may be accomplished through a direct
skip (a decedent leaves assets to grandchildren rather than children) or an indirect skip (assets are
left in a trust with income rights to children, and the corpus passing to the grandchildren on the
children’s death). The generation skipping tax rate is 45%. Relatively little revenue has been
collected from the generation skipping tax because the tax has been successful in eliminating 31
generation skipping transfers that are above the limit.
Charitable deductions can also be used to avoid estate and gift taxes (and income taxes as well).
For example, if a charity can be given rights to an asset during a fixed period (through a fixed
annuity, or a fixed percentage of the asset’s value), with the remainder going to the donor’s
children or other heirs, estate taxes can be avoided if the period of the trust is overstated (by being
based on a particular individual life that is likely to be shorter than the actuarial life). Although
restrictions have now been applied to limit reference persons to related parties, in the past so-
called “vulture trusts” that recruited a completely unrelated person with a diminished life 32
expectancy were used to avoid tax.
Assets can also be transferred to charity while maintaining control through private foundations.
Private foundations allow an individual or his or her heirs to direct the disposition of funds in the
foundations for charitable purposes and continue to exercise power and control over the assets.
As noted earlier, some estate planning techniques are used to provide maximum benefits of the
marital deduction plus the exclusion and lower rates; these approaches can also involve the use of
trusts, such as the Qualified Terminable Interest Property (QTIP). These plans may permit the
invasion of the corpus for emergency reasons.
Finally, a significant way of reducing estate taxes is to reduce the valuation of assets. A lower
valuation can be achieved by transferring assets into a family partnership with many interests so
that one party is not technically able to sell at a “market price” without agreement from the other
owners to sell, a circumstance that the courts have seen as lowering the value of even obviously
marketable assets, such as publicly traded stocks (the minority interest discount). Undervaluation
can also be argued through the claim that a sale of a large block of stock (a “fire sale”) would
reduce asset value or, with a family-owned business, that the death of the owner (or a “key man”)
lowers the value substantially. A fractional interest in a property (such as real estate) may also
qualify for a discount. Discounts may also be allowed for special use property whose market
value may be higher than the value of the property in its current use.
Estate planning techniques complicate the tax law, increase the resources in the economy devoted
to planning and also increase the administrative burden on the IRS especially when such cases go
to court. Some claims have been made that the administrative costs and costs to taxpayers
comprise a large part of the revenues. However, a recent study set the costs of complying with the
estate tax at 6 to 9% of revenues. Moreover, an interesting argument was also made in that study
that the inducement to settle affairs provided by the existence of an estate tax may be beneficial as

31 For a description see CRS Report 95-416, Federal Estate, Gift, and Generation-Skipping Taxes: A Description of
Current Law, by John R. Luckey.
32 See Schmalbeck, op cit. The reference individual cannot be terminal (have a life expectancy of less than a year),
however.





it encourages individuals to get their affairs in order and avoid costly and difficult disputes among 33
heirs.
Of course, the administrative and compliance costs are, themselves, in part a consequence of the
design of the tax. If the estate tax were revised to mitigate some of the need for tax planning, the
administrative and compliance costs might be lower.
The high tax rates for some estates and the lack of third-party reporting mechanisms suggest that
compliance may be a problem, although a large fraction of returns with large estates are audited.
Estimates of the estate “tax gap,” or the fraction of revenues that are not collected, have varied
considerably; a recent estimate suggests about 31% of estates and gift taxes are not collected, 34
although the authors of previous estimates suggest that this measure is very difficult to estimate.
In theory, the federal credit for state death taxes eliminated the incentive for states to “race to the
bottom” of state estate tax rates and burden. Lower state liability simply increased federal liability
by an equal amount. In short, the state credit was simply a federal transfer to states contingent
upon the state’s maintenance of an estate tax. The credit also reduced the federal tax burden of the
estate and gift tax. The highest effective credit rate was of 16% of the gross estate value which
reduced the highest federal rate of 55% to 39% (before EGTRRA).
In 2005, the “credit for state death taxes” was eliminated and replaced with a deduction for those
taxes. Many states have relied on the federal credit for their estate tax and will need to modify
their tax laws to continue collecting their estate and inheritance taxes. Under current state laws, 35
“... there will be 29 states that have no state death tax in 2005.”

One option is to eliminate the estate tax. This approach has been taken in the 2001 tax cut bill, the
Economic Growth and Tax Relief Reconciliation Act of 2001 (EGTRRA, P.L. 107-16). However,
the legislation sunsets after 2010, reverting to what the law would have been in 2011 if not for
EGTRRA. During the phase-out period, the estate tax will still generate revenue, thus
understating the full fiscal impact (revenue loss) of complete repeal. Immediate repeal of the
estate and gift tax would cost up to $662 billion, whereas the estimated 10-year revenue cost of
the temporary repeal of the estate tax under EGTRRA was $138 billion.

33 See Davenport and Soled, op cit. This study also reviewed a variety of other studies of estate tax compliance costs.
34 See U.S. Department of The Treasury, Office of Tax Policy, A Comprehensive Strategy for Reducing the Tax Gap,
Sept. 26, 2006, p. 6, and Martha Eller, Brian Erard and Chih-Chin Ho, The Magnitude and Determinants of Federal
Estate Tax Noncompliance, in William G. Gale, James R. Hines Jr., and Joel B. Slemrod, eds., Rethinking Estate and
Gift Taxation, pp. 375-421. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press, 2001.
35 Harley Duncan, “State Responses to Estate Tax Changes Enacted as Part of the Economic Growth and Tax Relief
Reconciliation Act of 2001 (EGTRRA),” State Tax Notes, Dec. 2, 2002, p. 615.





The Bush Administration’s FY2009 budget proposal contained a proposal to permanently repeal
the estate and gift tax beginning in 2010 by repealing the EGTRRA sunset. The revenue loss from
that proposal would be $522 billion over the 2009-2018 budget window. Most of the revenue loss
accrues in the out years of the proposal; from 2014 to 2018, the proposal would cost $372.3
billion in lost federal revenue.
Several of the compromise proposals mentioned earlier in this report would both increase the
exemption (eliminating the credit structure) amount and lower the rate. For example, H.R. 3170
would set the exemption at $5 million for each spouse ($10 million per couple) and lower the tax
rate to 35%, while H.R. 4235 would set the exemption at $3 million per decedent and reduce
marginal estate tax rates by 20%. No potential revenue loss estimates are available for either
proposal.
In 2010, the estate tax will be replaced by a tax on the capital gains of heirs when an inherited
asset is sold. The new law includes an exemption from carryover basis for capital gains of $1.3
million (and an additional $3 million for a surviving spouse). There are efficiency losses to taxing
capital gains of heirs on inherited assets because such taxation would increase the lock-in effect.
The lock-in effect occurs when potential taxpayers hold onto their assets because the anticipated
tax on the gain. If the asset value grows from generation to generation, the lock-in effect becomes
stronger and stronger. Some analysts have suggested that the result of the lock-in effect will be
familial asset hoarding. Legislation that repeals the EGTRRA sunset would retain this treatment
of capital gains.
Both taxation of gains at death and carry-over basis may be complicated by lack of information
by the executor on the basis of assets (some of which may have been originally inherited by the
decedent). Indeed, a proposal in the 1970s to provide carry-over basis was never put into place
because of protests, some associated with the problem of determining the basis. This problem
may be less serious for EGTRRA because of the carry-over of basis exemption.
Allowing constructive realization or carryover basis may further complicate estate planning if an
exemption were allowed, because it would be advantageous to pick those assets with the largest
amounts of appreciation for the exclusion or carryover basis. In addition, since the tax arising
from carryover basis would depend on the heir’s income tax rates, revenues could be saved by
allocating appreciated assets to heirs with the lowest expected tax rates.
Changing from the current step-up basis for inherited assets to a carryover basis, as enacted by
EGTRRA, will also affect the life insurance choices of taxpayers. Generally, EGTRRA will likely
encourage taxpayers to invest more in life insurance than other investments. Under current tax
law, the appreciation of assets held in life insurance policies is not subject to capital gains taxes.
Also, the payout from these policies, usually in cash to heirs, is not subject to income taxes and
effectively receives a stepped up basis. The switch to carryover basis at death would then favor
life insurance policies over other assets that are subject to capital gains taxes at death (assuming





the heir liquidates the assets). The anticipated change to more assets held in life insurance policies
will likely reduce the revenue generated by capital gains taxes.
If the estate tax is not repealed, farms and family businesses may be targeted for further relief by 36
increases in the special exemptions for farm and business assets. Because of the asset
distribution of estates, almost all decedents with significant farm or business assets would likely
not pay an estate tax. While this approach would be effective at targeting family farms and
businesses for relief, it would exacerbate a general concern with the estate and gift tax—the
unfairness of a differential treatment of owners of these business and farm assets compared to
those with other forms of assets. Why should a wealthy individual whose assets are in a closely
held corporation escape estate and gift tax on his or her assets, while an individual who holds
shares in a publicly traded corporation pay a tax?
Larger exemptions also encourage wealthy decedents to convert other property into business or
farm property to take advantage of the special exemptions. An incentive already exists to shift
property into this exempt form and it would have been exacerbated by an expansion of the
exemption.
Many pre-EGTRRA proposals were intended to modify rather than completely repeal the estate
tax. Some of these proposals may be revisited as the subset provision in EGTRRA nears. The
proposed revisions would have focused on eliminating estate tax avoidance schemes or at fixing
current inconsistencies in the estate tax law. The issues presented here are still relevant for the
near term for two reasons. One, during the phase-out period, the estate and gift is still part of the
tax code. Two, the gift tax is retained even after eventual repeal of the estate tax.
Phase out of Unified Credit for Largest Estates. This provision would allow for a phase out of the
unified credit as well as the lower rates, by extending the bubble. This provision would cause all
assets in large estates to be taxed at the top rate of 45%.
Impose Consistent Valuation Rules. Analysts have proposed that valuation of assets be the same
for income tax purposes as for estate tax purposes. Basically, it is advantageous to overvalue
assets for purposes of the income tax, so as to minimize any future capital gains tax liability.
Conversely, its advantageous to undervalue assets to minimize estate tax liability. In addition to
requiring consistency in valuation, some have proposed that donors report the basis of assets
given as gifts. Currently, assets transferred by gift and then sold do not benefit from step-up in
basis even though the donor is not required to report the basis to the donee.
Modify the Rules for the Allocation of Basis. Under current law, a transaction that is part gift and
part sale assigns a basis to the asset for the donee that is the larger of the fair market value or the
amount actually paid. The donor pays a tax on the difference between amount paid and his basis

36 For more on the estate tax and its effect on family businesses, see CRS Report RL33070, Estate Taxes and Family
Businesses: Economic Issues, by Jane G. Gravelle and Steven Maguire.





and may frequently recognize no gain. This proposal would allocate basis proportionally to the 37
gift and sale portions.
Eliminate Stepped up Basis on Survivor’s Share of Community Property. Under present law, in
common law states, half of property held jointly by a married couple is included in the first
decedent’s gross estate and that half is thus eligible for step-up in basis for purposes of future
capital gains. In community property states, however, where all properties acquired during
marriage are deemed community property, a step up in basis is available for all community
property, not just the half that is allocated to the decedent spouse. The reason for this rule, which
is quite old, was the presumption in the past that property in a common law state would have been
held by the husband (who would have acquired it) and thus would all have been eligible for step-
up, while only one half of property in community property states would have been deemed to be
held by the husband and be eligible for step up. This older treatment, it is argued, was made
obsolete by changes in 1981 that determined that only half of any jointly held property would be
included in the estate regardless of how the property was acquired, and thus made the step up
apply to only one half of this type of property. Thus, currently couples in community property
states are being treated more favorably than those in common law states.
A reservation with this treatment is that property that could be allocated to one spouse in a
common law state may not be able to escape the community property treatment in a community
property states, and common law states may now be favored if these assets in common law states
tend to be held by the first decedent. However, couples in community property states may be able
to convert to separate property by agreement, and thereby take advantage of the same planning
opportunities as those in common law states.
Modify QTIP Rules. Under present law, an individual may obtain a marital deduction for amounts
left in trust to a spouse under a Qualified Terminable Interest Property (QTIP) trust, with one
requirement being that the second spouse must then include the trust amounts in their own estate.
In some cases the second estate has argued that there is a defect in the trust arrangement so that
the trust amount is not included in the second spouse’s estate (even though a deduction was
allowed for it in the first spouse’s estate). This provision would require inclusion in the second
spouse’s estate for any amount excluded in the first spouse’s estate.
Eliminate Non-Business Valuation Discount . This provision would require that marketable assets
be valued at the fair market value (i.e., there would be no valuation discounts for holding assets in
a family partnership or for “fire-sale” dispositions).
Eliminate the Exception for a Retained Interest in Personal Residences from Gift Tax Rules.
Under current law, when a gift is made but the grantor retains an interest, that retained interest is
valued at zero (making the size of the gift and the gift tax larger). In the case of a personal
residence, however, the retained interest is valued based on actuarial tables. In general, retained
interests are only allowed to be deducted from the fair market of the gift (reducing gift taxes) if

37 For example, suppose an asset with a basis of $50,000 but a market value of $100,000 is sold to the donee for
$50,000. The donor would realize no gain and the gift amount would be $50,000, with the donee having a basis of
$50,000. Eventually, the gain would be taxed when the donee sold the property, but that tax would be delayed.
However, if the asset were divided into a gift of $50,000 with a basis of $25,000 and a sale of $50,000 with a basis of
$50,000, the donor would realize a gain of $25,000; the donee would now have a basis of $75,000. Half of the gain
would be subject to tax immediately.





they can be objectively valued (and hence are allowed for certain types of trusts, such as those
that pay an annuity).
Disallow Annual Gift Taxes in a Crummey Trust. As noted earlier, the annual gift exclusion is not
available for gifts placed in trust unless certain rules are met, but a Crummey trust, which allows
some right of withdrawal, is eligible. This revision would allow gifts in trust to be deductible only
if the only beneficiary is the individual, and if the trust does not terminate before the individual
dies, the assets will be in the beneficiary’s estate. These rules are similar to generation skipping
taxes.
Reduce the Annual Gift Tax Exclusion. The annual gift tax exclusion allows significant amounts
to be transferred free of tax and also plays a role in transferring insurance out of the estate (by
using the annual gift tax exclusion to pay the premium). While some gift tax exclusion is
probably desirable for simplification purposes, the $12,000 exclusion’s role in estate tax
avoidance could be reduced by reducing its size. An alternative change that would limit the use of
the annual exclusion in tax avoidance approaches would be a single exclusion per donor (or some
aggregate limit per donor), to prevent the multiplication of the excluded amount by gifts to
several children and those children’s spouses and the use of techniques such as the Crummey
trust.
Allow Inheritance of Marital Deductions or Lower Rates. One of the complications of estate
planning is maximizing the use of the exemption and lower rate brackets by a married couple. In
this case, while it may be economically and personally desirable to pass the entire estate (or most
of the estate) to the surviving spouse, minimizing taxes would require passing to others at least
the exemption amount and perhaps more to take some advantage as well of the lower rate
brackets. Such complex situations could be avoided by allowing the surviving spouse to inherit
any unused deduction and lower rate brackets so that the couple’s full deductions and lower rates
could be utilized regardless of how much was left to the surviving spouse.
Allow Gift Tax Treatment Only on Final and Actual Transfer. Many of the tax avoidance
techniques with charitable gifts involve over-valuation of a deductible interest. For example, a
gift may be made of the remainder interest after an annuity has been provided to a charitable
organization . The larger the value of the charitable annuity, the smaller the value of the gift (and
the gift tax). One way to over-value an annuity is to allow the annuity to extend to a particular
individual’s lifetime, when that individual has a shorter life than the actuarial tables indicate.
Similarly, a way to transfer income via the gift tax exclusion without the recipient having control
over it is to place it in a Crummey trust. Even if the individual is able to exercise withdrawal
rights, the expectation of not receiving future gifts if the assets are withdrawn in violation of the
donor’s wishes may mean that such rights will never be exercised. A rule that excludes all assets
placed in trusts from consideration for the gift tax would eliminate this mechanism.
These types of valuation techniques could be addressed by only allowing the gift tax to be
imposed at the time of the actual final transfer. In such a case, no actuarial valuation would be
necessary and no trust mechanisms would be available.
Valuation of Assets. One option is to disallow discounts for property that has a market value (such
as bonds and publicly traded stock) regardless of the form the asset is held in, as suggested by the
administration tax proposals. Such a change would prevent the avoidance technique of placing
assets into a family partnership or similar arrangement and then arguing that the property has lost
market value because it would require agreement of the heirs to sell it. In addition, other limits on





valuation discounts could be imposed. For example, blockage discounts based on “fire sale”
arguments could be disallowed. Such a provision might allow for an adjustment if the property is
immediately sold at such a lower price.
Include Life Insurance Proceeds in the Base. Some tax avoidance techniques are associated with
shifting life insurance proceeds out of the estate by shifting to another owner.
Switch to an Inheritance Tax. Some authors have suggested that an inheritance tax should be
substituted for the estate tax. Some states have inheritance taxes. An estate tax applies to the total
assets left by the decedent. An inheritance tax would be applied separately to assets received by
each of the heirs. If tax rates are progressive, smaller taxes would be applied the greater the
number of beneficiaries of the assets. One reason for such a change would, therefore, be to
encourage more dispersion of wealth among heirs, since taxes would be lower (assuming
exemptions and graduated rates) if split among more recipients. In addition, under an inheritance
tax the tax rate can be varied according to the status of the heir (son vs. cousin, for example). At
the same time, one can see more avoidance complications arising from an inheritance tax.

The analysis in this report has suggested that some of the arguments used for and against
maintaining the estate tax may be questioned or of lesser import than is popularly assumed. For
example, there is little evidence that the estate tax has much effect on savings (and therefore on
output); indeed, estate taxes could easily increase rather than reduce savings. Similarly, only a
tiny fraction of farms and small businesses face the estate and gift tax and it has been estimated
that the majority of those who do have sufficient non-business assets to pay the tax. Moreover,
only a small potion of the estate tax is collected from these family owned farms and small
businesses, so that dramatically reducing estate tax rates or eliminating the tax for the purpose of
helping these family businesses is not very target efficient.
Although the estate tax does contribute to the progressivity of the tax system, this progressivity is
undermined, to an undetermined degree, by certain estate tax avoidance techniques. Of course,
one alternative is to broaden the estate tax base by restricting some of these estate planning
techniques. At the same time progressivity could be achieved by other methods.
On the other hand, arguments that the estate tax is a back-up for the income escaping the capital
gains tax, would not support the current high rates of the estate tax, which should be lowered to

20% or less to serve this purpose.


More intangible arguments, such as the argument that inheritances are windfalls that should be
taxed at higher rates on the one hand, or that death is an undesirable time to levy a tax and that
transferred assets have already been subject to taxes, are more difficult to assess but remain
important issues in the determination of the desirability of estate and gift taxes.






Table A-1. The Filing Requirement and Unified Credit
Year of Death Filing Requirement or Equivalent Exemption Unified Credit
2004 and 2005 $1,500,000 $555,800
2006 through 2008 $2,000,000 $780,800
2009 $3,500,00$1,525,80
2010 estate tax repealed estate tax repealed
2011 and after $1,000,000 $345,800
Table A-2. Gross Estate Value for Returns Filed in 2006
Size of All Taxable Gross Estate Gross Estate Value Percent Taxable
Gross Returns Returns Value All Returns Taxable Returns Estate Tax
Estate (in 000s) (in 000s) Returns
All Returns 49,050 22,798 211,460,077 116,093,783 46.48%
$2.0 to $3.5 18,857 9,043 48,672,849 23,489,093 47.96%
million
$3.5 to $5.0 5,629 2,951 23,282,496 12,260,044 52.42%
million
$5.0 to $10.0 5,053 2,664 34,142,415 18,224,109 52.72%
million
$10.0 to $20 1,708 1,004 22,983,958 13,562,562 58.78%
million
over $20.0 939 614 54,430,509 37,470,301 65.39%
million
Source: Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income, Estate Tax Returns Filed in 2006, IRS, SOI unpublished
data, November 2007.
Table A-3. Allowable Deductions on 2006 Returns
(Sorted by Total Value)
Returns with Deduction Value of Deductions (in 000s)
Deduction
Total Taxable Total Taxable
Total deductions 49,019 22,777 $94,504,013 $28,679,871
Bequests to surviving spouse 21,867 1,946 $65,831,439 $10,921,253
Charitable deductions 9,522 5,331 $17,590,332 $10,431,999
Debts and mortgages 35,873 19,793 $7,909,327 $3,964,023
Executor’s commissions 16,701 13,518 $1,265,158 $1,098,702
Other expenses and losses 30,482 19,723 $1,241,842 $1,096,563
Attorney’s fees 30,003 19,920 $1,047,600 $804,368





Returns with Deduction Value of Deductions (in 000s)
Deduction
Total Taxable Total Taxable
Funeral expenses 42,858 21,776 $415,140 $201,506
State death taxes paid 12,254 8,702 $2,770,955 $2,542,518
Source: Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income, Estate Tax Returns Filed in 2006, IRS, SOI unpublished
data, November 2007.
Table A-4. 2008 Estate Tax Rate Schedule
Taxable Estate to Current Statutory Rate
Value From (in Percent)
$0 $10,000 18
$10,001 $20,000 20
$20,001 $40,000 22
$40,001 $60,000 24
$60,001 $80,000 26
$80,001 $100,000 28
$100,001 $150,000 30
$150,001 $250,000 32
$250,001 $500,000 34
$500,001 $750,000 37
$750,001 $1,000,000 39
$1,000,001 $1,250,000 41
$1,250,001 $1,500,000 43
$1,500,001 and over 45
Table A-5. Repealed Credit for State Death Taxes
Taxable Estate Value Current Statutory
(less the $60,000 to Credit Rate
exemption) (in Percent)
$0 $40,000 0
$40,001 $90,000 .8
$90,001 $140,000 1.6
$140,001 $240,000 2.4
$240,001 $440,000 3.2
$440,001 $640,000 4.0
$640,001 $840,000 4.8
$840,001 $1,040,000 5.6
$1,040,001 $1,540,000 6.4





Taxable Estate Value Current Statutory
(less the $60,000 to Credit Rate
exemption) (in Percent)
$1,540,001 $2,040,000 7.2
$2,040,001 $2,540,000 8.0
$2,540,001 $3,040,000 8.8
$3,040,001 $3,540,000 9.6
$3,540,001 $4,040,000 10.4
$4,040,001 $5,040,000 11.2
$5,040,001 $6,040,000 12.0
$6,040,001 $7,040,000 12.8
$7,040,001 $8,040,000 13.6
$8,040,001 $9,040,000 14.4
$9,040,001 $10,040,000 15.2
Note: In 2005, the credit was repealed and replaced with a deduction.
Table A-6. Wealth Distribution of Taxable Returns Filed in 2006
Size of Taxable Gross Taxable Net Estate Percent of Percent Gross
Gross Returns Estate Value Tax Taxable Estate Taxable Estate
Estate (in 000s) (in 000s) Returns Tax Value
All Returns 22,798 $116,093,783 $24,652,654 100.00% 100.00%
2.0 to 3.5 9,043 $23,489,093 $3,426,895 39.67% 20.23%
million
3.5 to 5.0 2,951 $12,260,044 $2,867,297 12.94% 10.57%
million
5.0 to 10.0 2,664 $18,224,109 $5,201,526 11.69% 15.70%
million
10.0 to 20 1,004 $13,562,562 $4,045,908 4.40% 11.68%
million
over 20.0 614 $37,470,301 $8,475,110 2.69% 32.28%
million
Source: Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of Income, Estate Tax Returns Filed in 2006, IRS, SOI unpublished
data, November 2007.
Donald J. Marples Jane G. Gravelle
Specialist in Public Finance Senior Specialist in Economic Policy
dmarples@crs.loc.gov, 7-3739 jgravelle@crs.loc.gov, 7-7829