Fixed Exchange Rates, Floating Exchange Rates:What Have We Learned?







Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress



Congress is generally interested in promoting a stable and prosperous world economy. Stable
currency exchange rate regimes are a key component to stable economic growth. This report
explains the difference between fixed exchange rates, floating exchange rates, and currency
boards/unions, and outlines the advantages and disadvantages of each. Floating exchange rate
regimes are market determined; values fluctuate with market conditions. In fixed exchange rate
regimes, the central bank is dedicated to using monetary policy to maintain the exchange rate at a
predetermined price. In theory, under such an arrangement, a central bank would be unable to use
monetary policy to promote any other goal; in practice, there is limited leeway to pursue other
goals without disrupting the exchange rate. Currency boards and currency unions, or “hard pegs,”
are extreme examples of a fixed exchange rate regime where the central bank is truly stripped of
all its capabilities other than converting any amount of domestic currency to a foreign currency at
a predetermined price.
The main economic advantages of floating exchange rates are that they leave the monetary and
fiscal authorities free to pursue internal goals—such as full employment, stable growth, and price
stability—and exchange rate adjustment often works as an automatic stabilizer to promote those
goals. The main economic advantage of fixed exchange rates is that they promote international
trade and investment, which can be an important source of growth in the long run, particularly for
developing countries. The merits of floating compared to fixed exchange rates for any given
country depends on how interdependent that country is with its neighbors. If a country’s economy
is highly reliant on its neighbors for trade and investment and experiences economic shocks
similar to its neighbors’, there is little benefit to monetary and fiscal independence, and the
country is better off with a fixed exchange rate. If a country experiences unique economic shocks
and is economically independent of its neighbors, a floating exchange rate can be a valuable way
to promote macroeconomic stability. A political advantage of a currency board or currency union
in a country with a profligate past is that it “ties the hands” of the monetary and fiscal authorities,
making it harder to finance budget deficits by printing money.
Recent experience with economic crisis in Mexico, East Asia, Russia, Brazil, and Turkey suggests
that fixed exchange rates can be prone to currency crises that can spill over into wider economic
crises. This is a factor not considered in the earlier exchange rate literature, in part because
international capital mobility plays a greater role today than it did in the past. These experiences
suggest that unless a country has substantial economic interdependence with a neighbor to which
it can fix its exchange rate, floating exchange rates may be a better way to promote
macroeconomic stability, provided the country is willing to use its monetary and fiscal policy in a
disciplined fashion. The collapse of Argentina’s currency board in 2002 suggests that such
arrangements do not get around the problems with fixed exchange rates, as their proponents
claimed. This report does not track legislation and will be updated as events warrant.






What Determines Exchange Rates?.................................................................................................1
Floating Exchange Rates.................................................................................................................2
Hard Pegs and Soft Pegs..................................................................................................................5
Currency Boards or Currency Unions.......................................................................................5
Economic Advantages to a Hard Peg..................................................................................6
Political Advantages to a Currency Board or Union...........................................................7
Fixed Exchange Rates...............................................................................................................8
Economic Advantages of a Fixed Exchange Rate..............................................................9
Political Advantages of a Fixed Exchange Rate...............................................................10
What Have Recent Crises Taught Us About Exchange Rates?......................................................11
Figure 1. Exchange Rates of Asian Crisis Countries.....................................................................13
Table 1. Differences in Types of Currency Arrangements...............................................................6
Table A-1. Economic Interdependence of Selected Developed Countries and Hong Kong..........19
Appendix. How Interdependent Are International Economies?....................................................18
Author Contact Information..........................................................................................................20





prosperous world economy is beneficial to the American economy, especially given our
robust international trade sector, and it is thought to bring political benefits as well,
through its salutary effect on the political stability of our allies. Congress plays a role in A


promoting a stable and prosperous world economy. Congressional interest in currency exchange
rates is twofold. First, Congress has an interest in determining the most appropriate exchange rate
regime for the United States to promote domestic economic stability. Second, it has an interest in
understanding and influencing the exchange rate regime choices of other nations. Stable exchange
rate regimes are a key element of a stable macroeconomic framework, and a stable
macroeconomic framework is a prerequisite to a country’s development prospects. The collapse
of a fixed exchange rate regime was central to every important international economic crisis since
the mid-1990s—the 1994 Mexican peso crisis, the Asian economic crisis of 1997, the Russian
debt default of 1998, the Brazilian devaluation of 1999, the Turkish crisis of 2001, and the
Argentine crisis of 2002.
This report evaluates the benefits and drawbacks of different types of exchange rate regimes from
the perspective of their effects on macroeconomic stability. It focuses on three major types of
exchange rate regimes: a floating exchange rate, a fixed exchange rate, and “hard pegs,” such as a
currency board or a currency union. While there are permutations on these regimes too numerous
to mention, a thorough understanding of these three will allow the reader to understand any
permutation equally well. In the case of exchange rate regimes “one size does not fit all”—
different countries have very different political and economic conditions that make some regimes
more suitable than others.

At times, the exchange rate is erroneously imagined to be an incidental value that can be
sustained by the good intentions of government and undermined by the malevolence of greedy
speculators. Economic theory holds it to be a value that is far more fundamental. It is the value at
which two countries trade goods and services and the value at which investors from one country
purchase the assets of another country. As such, it is dependent on the two countries’ fundamental
macroeconomic conditions, such as its inflation, growth, and saving rates. Thus, it is generally
accepted that the value of the exchange rate cannot be predictably altered (for long) unless the
country’s macroeconomic conditions are modified relative to those of its trading partners.
Many view the volatility of floating exchange rates as proof that speculation and irrational
behavior, rather than economic fundamentals, drive exchange rate values. Empirical evidence
supports the view that changes in exchange rate values are not well correlated with changes in 1
economic data in the short run. But this evidence does not prove that economic theory is wrong.
Although floating exchange rate values change frequently, and at times considerably, there are
important economic conditions that change frequently in ways that cannot be measured. Factors
such as investors’ perceptions of future profitability and riskiness cannot be accurately measured,
yet changes in these factors can have profound influence on exchange rate values. Economists
have had more success at correlating long run exchange rate movements with changes in
economic fundamentals.

1 For example, see Robert Flood and Andrew Rose, “Fixing exchange rates: A Virtual Quest for Fundamentals,
Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 36, no. 1, December 1995, p. 1.



A decision by a government to influence the value of its exchange rate, therefore, is likely to
succeed only if its overall macroeconomic conditions are altered. Government does have tools at
its disposal to alter aggregate demand in the short run—fiscal and monetary policy. Fiscal policy
refers to increasing or decreasing the government’s budget surplus (or deficit) in order to increase 2
or decrease the amount of aggregate spending in the economy. Monetary policy refers to
increasing or decreasing short-term interest rates through manipulation of the money supply in 3
order to decrease or increase the amount of aggregate spending in the economy. For example,
other things being equal, lower interest rates lead to more investment spending, one component of
aggregate spending. Furthermore, fiscal and monetary policy influence interest rates differently,
and interest rates are the key determinant of the exchange rate. Expansionary fiscal policy is
likely to raise interest rates and “crowd out” private investment while expansionary monetary
policy, or reducing short-term interest rates, is likely to temporarily lower interest rates.
Maintaining a fixed exchange rate requires continuous policy adjustment. Although perhaps
theoretically feasible, it would be impossible in practice to operate a timely or precise enough
fiscal policy to maintain a fixed exchange rate as long as fiscal policy must be legislated. Thus,
maintaining a fixed exchange rate has been delegated to the monetary authority in practice.
Intervening in foreign exchange markets directly is equivalent to changing monetary policy if the
intervention is “unsterilized.” When a central bank sells foreign currency to boost the exchange
rate, it takes the domestic currency it receives in exchange out of circulation, decreasing the
money supply. Often, it prints new money to replace the domestic currency that has been
removed from circulation—referred to as sterilization—but economic theory suggests that when 4
it does so, it negates the intervention’s effect on the exchange rate.
If a government wishes to alter a floating exchange rate or maintain a fixed exchange rate, it may
do so by altering monetary policy but only if it is willing to abandon other macroeconomic goals
such as providing stable economic growth, preventing recessions, and maintaining a moderate, 5
stable inflation rate. The magnitude of response of the exchange rate to changes in monetary
policy is not likely to be constant or predictable over time, but under most circumstances policy
can eventually lead to the desired result if it is truly dedicated to achieving it. As discussed later,
problems with exchange rates usually arise when a government’s heart is not truly wedded to
achieving its stated goal.

The exchange rate arrangement maintained between the United States and all of its major trading
partners is known as a floating exchange rate regime. In a floating exchange rate regime, the
exchange rate is a price freely determined in the market by supply and demand. The dollar is

2 For more information, see CRS Report RL31235, The Economics of the Federal Budget Deficit, by Brian W. Cashell.
3 For more information, see CRS Report RL30354, Monetary Policy and the Federal Reserve: Current Policy and
Conditions, by Gail E. Makinen and Marc Labonte.
4 Similarly, if exchange rate intervention was undertaken by a government’s treasury, theory suggests it would have no
lasting effect on the exchange rate because the treasury cannot alter the money supply.
5 There is a caveat to this general principle: countries that maintain capital controls (laws that limit international
investment flows), such as China, may be able to maintain a fixed exchange rate and still have some latitude to use
monetary policy to influence the domestic economy. Capital controls may reduce capital inflows, however, although
this has not been a problem for China thus far.





purchased by foreigners in order to purchase goods or assets from the United States. Likewise,
U.S. citizens sell dollars and buy foreign currencies when they wish to purchase goods or assets 6
from foreign countries. The exchange rate is determined by whatever rate clears these markets.
Monetary and fiscal policy are not regularly or systematically used to influence the exchange 7
rate.
Thus, when the demand for U.S. goods or assets rises relative to the rest of the world, the
exchange rate value of the dollar will appreciate. This is necessary to restore balance or
equilibrium between the dollar value exported and the dollar value imported. Dollar appreciation
accomplishes this through two effects on the United States economy, all else being equal. First, it
makes foreign goods cheaper for Americans, which increases the purchasing power of American
income. This is known as the terms-of-trade effect. Second, it tends to offset the changes in
aggregate demand that first altered the exchange rate by making U.S. exports dearer and foreign 8
imports less expensive. The offset in demand may not be instantaneous or complete, but it helps
to make macroeconomic adjustment possible if wages and prices are not completely flexible.
When foreigners increase their demand for U.S. goods, aggregate demand in the United States
increases. If the United States is in a recession, this increase in aggregate demand would boost
growth in the short run. If economic growth in the United States is already robust, it would be
inflationary—there would be too many buyers (domestic and foreign) seeking the goods that
Americans can produce. Under a floating exchange rate, a substantial part of this increase in U.S.
aggregate demand would be offset by the appreciation in the dollar, which would push U.S.
exports and the production of U.S. import-competing goods back towards an equilibrium level.
By reducing aggregate demand, an appreciating dollar reduces inflationary pressures that might
otherwise result.
Likewise, if the foreign demand for U.S. assets increased, foreign capital would flow into the
United States, lowering interest rates and increasing investment spending and interest-sensitive
consumption spending (e.g., automobiles). Absent exchange rate adjustment, this would boost
U.S. aggregate demand. But because the greater demand for U.S. assets causes the dollar to
appreciate, the demand for U.S. exports and U.S. import-competing goods declines, offsetting the 9
increase in demand caused by the foreign capital inflow.

6 The dollar is also widely used as an international medium of exchange for transactions that do not involve American
goods or assets. These transactions have no effect on the exchange value of the dollar, however.
7 From time to time, governments and central banks in countries with floating exchange rates may enter the foreign
exchange market in an attempt to influence the exchange rate value. This is known as “managed floating” or “dirty
floating. Historically, such interventions have had patchy success. When they have failed, it has frequently been due to
the fact that intervention was not coupled with a change in monetary policy. Managed floating is very different from a
fixed exchange rate regime, where monetary policy is devoted to maintaining the exchange rate value on a continual
basis as its primary goal.
8 In reality, for reasons not entirely clear to economists, the prices of tradeable goods do not change as much or as
quickly as the ideal would suggest, making the negative effect of a floating exchange rate on trade smaller than
expected. An overview of this extensive literature is given in Maurice Obstfeld, “International Macroeconomics:
Beyond the Mundell-Fleming Model,” National Bureau of Economic Research, Working Paper 8369, pp. 12-18, July
2001.
9 This discussion assumes that changes in exchange rates are driven by changes in economic fundamentals. To the
extent that they are, floating exchange rates are an equilibrating force. But if exchange rates are dominated by non-
economic speculation—a proposal that economists have not been able to rule out empiricallythen movements in
floating exchange rates could be a destabilizing, rather than equilibrating, force. If this were true, it would weaken the
primary argument in favor of floating exchange rates. To the extent that exchange rates may be driven by both non-
(continued...)





Because floating exchange rates allow for automatic adjustment, they buffer the domestic
economy from external changes in international supply and demand. A floating exchange rate also
becomes another automatic outlet for internal adjustment. If the economy is growing too rapidly,
the exchange rate is likely to appreciate, which helps slow aggregate spending by slowing export
growth. While this is unfortunate for exporters, overall it may be preferable to the alternative—
higher inflation or a sharp contraction in fiscal or monetary policy to stamp out inflationary
pressures. If the economy is in recession with falling income, the exchange rate is likely to
depreciate, which will help boost overall growth through export growth even in the absence of 10
domestic recovery.
The maintenance of a floating exchange rate does not require support from monetary and fiscal
policy. This frees the government to focus monetary and fiscal policy on stabilizing the economy
in response to domestic changes in supply and demand. Fiscal and monetary policy usually can be
focused on domestic goals, such as maintaining price and output stability, without being 11
constrained by the policy’s effect on the exchange rate. The drawback to fiscal and monetary
autonomy, of course, is that governments are free to pursue ill-conceived policies if they desire, a
particular problem for developing countries historically. Many times, a floating exchange rate is
forced to act as an outlet for internal adjustment because poor fiscal and monetary policy have
made adjustment necessary, causing stress on the trade sector of the economy. This can be
thought of as a political, rather than an economic, drawback to floating exchange rates.
How valuable the macroeconomic adjustment mechanism that floating exchange rates provide
depends on the economic independence of the country. For countries that are closely tied to others
through trade and investment links, the ability to adjust policy independently has little value—
whatever is affecting one economy is probably affecting its neighbors as well. For countries like
the United States, whose economy is arguably more affected by internal factors than external
factors, flexible exchange rates allow significant internal adjustment. Trade is still a relatively
small portion of American GDP: exports are equivalent to about 10% of GDP, in comparison to a
country like Malaysia or Singapore where exports exceed 100% of GDP.
The economic drawback to floating exchange rates is that exchange rate volatility and uncertainty
may discourage the growth of trade and international investment. Many developing countries, in
particular, have pursued growth strategies that have focused on promoting trade and foreign
investment. Exchange rate uncertainty can be thought of as placing a cost on trade and
investment, and this cost discourages trade. For example, after an international sale has been
negotiated, one party to the transaction will not know what price he will ultimately receive in his
currency because upon payment the exchange rate may be higher or lower than when he made the
trade. If the exchange rate has depreciated, he will receive lower compensation than he had
expected. The cost of this uncertainty can be measured precisely—it is the cost of hedging, that is

(...continued)
economic speculation and economic fundamentals, a fixed exchange rate could be superior, but only if governments
could promptly, correctly, and calmly adjust exchange rates when fundamentals changed.
10 Two seminal papers in favor of floating exchange rates are Milton Friedman, “The Case for Flexible Exchange
Rates, in Essays in Positive Economics, The University of Chicago Press, (Chicago: 1953); and Harry Johnson, “The
Case for Flexible Exchange Rates, 1969” in Further Essays in Monetary Economics (Cambridge: Harvard University
Press, 1973).
11 The Treasury is often asked to explain its “dollar policy.” The most accurate explanation would be that its policy is to
use its macroeconomic tools to maintain domestic stability rather than exchange rate stability.





the cost to the exporter of buying an exchange rate forward contract or futures contract to lock in 12
a future exchange rate today.

The alternative to floating exchange rates are exchange rate regimes that fix the value of the
exchange rate to that of another country or countries. There are two broad types of fixed exchange
rates. “Hard pegs,” currency boards and currency unions, are considered first because they are the
most stark example of a fixed exchange rate arrangement. The second category considered is
fixed exchange rates, in which the link to the other currency or currencies is less direct, making
them “soft pegs.”
At the opposite end of the spectrum from floating exchange rates are arrangements where a
country gives up its exchange rate and monetary freedom entirely by tying itself to a foreign
country’s currency, what former IMF Deputy Director Stanley Fischer calls “hard pegs.” This can 13
be done through a currency board or a currency union. A currency board is a monetary
arrangement where a country keeps its own currency, but the central bank cedes all of its power to
alter interest rates, and monetary policy is tied to the policy of a foreign country. For example,
Hong Kong has a currency board linked to the U.S. dollar. Argentina had a similar arrangement
which it abandoned in 2002, during its economic crisis. In Argentina, for every peso of currency
in circulation the Argentine currency board held one dollar-denominated asset, and was forbidden
from buying and selling domestic assets. Thus, the amount of pesos in circulation could only
increase if there was a balance of payment surplus. In effect, the exchange rate at which
Argentina competed with foreign goods was set by the United States. Because exchange rate
adjustment was not possible, adjustment had to come through prices (i.e., inflation or deflation)
instead. Domestically, because the central bank could no longer alter the money supply to change
interest rates, the economy could only recover from peaks and valleys of the business cycle
through gradual price adjustment.
From an economic perspective, a currency union is very similar to a currency board. An example
of a currency union is the euro, which has been adopted by 13 members of the European Union.
The individual nations in the euro zone have no control over the money supply in their countries.
Instead, it is determined by two factors. First, the European Central Bank (ECB) determines the
money supply for the entire euro area by targeting short-term interest rates for the euro area as a
whole. Second, how much of the euro area’s money supply flows to, say, Ireland depends upon
Ireland’s net monetary transactions with the rest of the euro area. For this second reason, different
countries in the euro area have different inflation rates despite the fact that they share a common
monetary policy.

12 The cost of hedging may be higher in countries with small, undeveloped financial markets, another reason why
floating exchange rates may be less advantageous in small countries.
13 For more information, see CRS Report RL31093, A Currency Board as an Alternative to a Central Bank, by Marc
Labonte and Gail E. Makinen.





In a currency union such as the euro arrangement, each member of the euro has a vote in 14
determining monetary policy for the overall euro area. This is the primary difference from a
currency board—the country that has adopted a currency board has no say in the setting of
monetary policy by the country to which its currency board is tied. The countries of the euro also
share in the earnings of the ECB, known as seigniorage, just as they would if they had their own
currency.
Not all currency unions give all members a say in the determination of monetary policy, however.
For instance, when Ecuador, El Salvador, and Panama unilaterally adopted the U.S. dollar as their
currency, they gained no influence over the actions and decisions of the Federal Reserve. From a
macroeconomic perspective, a unilateral currency adoption and a currency board are
indistinguishable. Between these two arrangements, there are only two minor differences of note.
First, currency boards earn income on the dollar-denominated assets that they hold (another 15
example of seigniorage) while currency adopters do not. Second, investors may view a currency
union as a more permanent commitment than a currency board, particularly after the failure of
Argentina’s currency board. If this were the case, they would view the risks associated with
investment in the former to be lower.
Table 1. Differences in Types of Currency Arrangements
Independent Role in Setting Circulation of Seigniorage
National Monetary Monetary Policy National Currency Earnings
Policy
Currency Board No No Yes Yes
Joint Currency No Yes No Yes
Union
Unilateral
Currency No No No No
Adoption
The primary economic advantage of a hard peg comes through greater trade with other members
of the exchange rate arrangement. The volatility of floating exchange rates places a cost on the
export and import-competing sectors of the economy. Greater trade is widely seen to be an engine
of growth, particularly among developing countries. In a perfectly competitive world economy
without transaction costs, the cost of exchange rate volatility could be very large indeed. For
instance, U.S. exporters and domestic firms that compete with importers in 2000 faced one-third
higher prices than in 1995 as a result of the (floating) dollar’s one-third appreciation against its
main trading partners. Until the domestic price level fell by one-third, U.S. producers would be
uncompetitive, if all else is equal. (All else was not equal—exports continued to rise in the 1990s
despite the dollar’s appreciation.) Under a system of fixed exchange rates, U.S. exporters would

14 Specifically, each country is represented on the ECBs Governing Council, which determines monetary policy. The
ECB has operational independence from the European Commission, EU Council of Ministers, and the national
governments of the euro area, just as the Federal Reserve has operational independence from the U.S. Congress and
executive branch.
15 There have been congressional proposals to transfer seigniorage earnings to countries that dollarize in order to
encourage dollarization. For example, see H.R. 2617 in the 107th Congress.





not have been placed at this price disadvantage, all else being equal. Between small countries, a
hard peg is also thought to promote more efficient and competitive markets through lower
barriers to entry and greater economies of scale.
Hard pegs also encourage international capital flows.16 The encouragement of international
capital flows can enhance a country’s welfare in a couple of ways. First, it allows more
investment to take place in areas where saving is relatively scarce and rates of return are high, and
investment is key to sustainable growth. This makes both the borrower and the investor better off;
the former because more investment, and hence growth, is possible than otherwise would be, the
latter because they can now enjoy higher rates of return on their investment for a given amount of
risk than if limited to home investment. For developing countries, these investment gains can be
quite large. Because these countries have much lower capital-labor ratios than the developed
world, capital investment can yield relatively high returns for some time if a friendly economic
environment is constructed. On the other hand, international capital flows can change rapidly in
ways that can be destabilizing to developing countries, as will be discussed below.
Weighed against the gains of higher trade and international investment is the loss of the use of
fiscal and monetary policy to stabilize the economy. For countries highly integrated with their
exchange rate partners, this loss is small. For example, in the euro area, the business cycle of
many of the “core” economies (e.g., Germany and the Netherlands, or Belgium and France) have
been highly correlated. As long as Belgium does not face separate shocks from France, it does not
lose any stabilization capabilities by giving up the ability to set policy independently of France.
By sharing a currency, their fiscal and monetary policy can still be adjusted to respond jointly to
shared shocks to their economies, even if these shocks are not shared by the rest of the world—
the euro is free to adjust against the rest of the world’s currencies. Troubles only arise if shocks
harm one of these countries, but not its partners in the euro. In that case, there cannot be policy 17
adjustment for that country to compensate for the shock.
The previous explanation described the economic reasons for establishing currency boards or
currency unions. But it is probable that the primary reason for establishing them in developing
countries is based more on political reasons. As has been shown, these monetary arrangements tie
the hands of their country’s policymakers. For some countries, this is precisely what their
policymakers are trying to achieve—a way to prevent the reinstatement of policies from the “bad
old days.” The most stark example of the “bad old days” is the hyperinflation that many
developing countries experienced. For instance, in 1990, the year before Argentina adopted a
currency board, its inflation rate reached 2,314%. Stable growth is impossible when the price
mechanism has broken down in this way. The currency board quickly brought the inflation rate in

16 Hard pegs encourage foreign investment for slightly different reasons than they encourage trade. With trade, there is
the danger under a floating exchange rate that a one-time appreciation will make your exporters uncompetitive until
domestic prices adjust. Because the return on foreign investment is typically denominated in the foreign currency, a
one-time exchange rate depreciation would lower the profitability of the investment held at the time of the depreciation.
But it would have no effect on the profitability of new investment after the depreciation had ended.
17 Although fiscal policy can still be used as an adjustment mechanism in countries with hard pegs, there are constraints
on its effectiveness in most of these countries. In the euro area, countries are legally forbidden from running fiscal
deficits greater than 3% of GDP (although that rule has recently been flouted). In developing countries, fiscal policy is
constrained by the willingness of investors to purchase their sovereign debt, and investors have proven much less
willing to finance developing country deficits than deficits in the developed world.





Argentina down to single digits. Whenever a country’s inflation rate gets extremely high, it is a
reflection of its fiscal policy. Large budget deficits cannot be financed through the sale of debt
instruments, so they are instead financed through the printing of money. Thus, a currency board
prevents irresponsible fiscal policy by preventing monetary policy from supporting it.
Similarly, Ecuador “dollarized” in 2000—adopting the U.S. dollar and largely discontinuing the
use of its own currency—at a time of economic crisis with the hope that it would renew investor
confidence. Although extremely high inflation had not yet become a problem, events leading up
to dollarization appeared to be pointing in that direction. The country’s banking system had
collapsed, its economy had shrunk by more than 7% in 1999, low oil prices and natural disaster
had caused budget financing problems, and it had defaulted on some of its sovereign debt.
Investors had become very concerned that inflationary monetary policy would be used to solve its
fiscal problems, and dollarization quelled these fears by eliminating that policy option.
Economic analysis sheds little light on the choice between floating exchange rates and a currency
board arrangement when the decision is motivated by the desire to find a political arrangement
that will prevent the pursuit of bad policies. Economic analysis can identify bad policy; it cannot
explain why it is pursued or how to prevent its recurrence. A currency board is not the only way
to tie the hands of policymakers; various rules and targets have been devised to eliminate policy
discretion that could be used with a floating exchange rate. A currency board may be a more final
commitment, and hence harder to renege on, than rules and targets, however. Then again,
Argentina proved that even currency boards are not permanent. In any case, the political problem
of countries monetizing budget deficits seems to be waning. Since 2000, the annual inflation rate
in developing countries has averaged about 6%. If current trends continue, in the future there may
be fewer countries who find it advantageous to accept the harsh medicine of hard pegs to solve 18
their political shortcomings.
Hard pegs are also seen by both proponents and opponents as a means to foster political
integration, a topic beyond the scope of this report. This was a primary consideration behind the
adoption of the euro.
In a traditional fixed exchange rate regime, the government has agreed to buy or sell any amount
of currency at a predetermined rate. That rate may be linked to one foreign currency or (unlike a
currency board) it may be linked to a basket of foreign currencies. In theoretical models, where
capital is perfectly mobile and investors consider all countries to be alike, fixed exchange rates
would necessarily be functionally equivalent to a currency board. Any attempt to unilaterally
influence one’s interest rates, through monetary or fiscal policy, would be unsustainable because
capital would flow in or out of the country until interest rates had returned to the worldwide level.
In reality, results are not quite so stark. There are transaction costs to investment. Investors
demand different risk premiums of different countries, and these risk premiums change over time.
There is a strong bias among investors worldwide, particularly in developed countries, to keep 19
more of one’s wealth invested domestically than economic theory would suggest. Due to these

18 Michael Mussa et al., “Exchange Rates in an Increasingly Integrated World Economy,IMF Occasional Paper 193,
2000, p. 17.
19 If individuals saw all countries as being equal, to achieve portfolio diversification the average American investor
(continued...)





factors, interest rate differentials, which should be theoretically impossible, are abundant. For
instance, interest rates in France and Germany should entail similar risks. Thus, anytime French
interest rates exceeded German rates, capital should flow from Germany to France until the rates
equalized again. Yet the commercial interest reference rate, as measured by the OECD, between
these two countries has varied by as much as 1.61 percentage points between 1993 and the
adoption of the euro in 1999.
As a result, countries with fixed exchange rates have limited freedom to use monetary and fiscal
policy to pursue domestic goals without causing their exchange rate to become unsustainable. By
contrast, countries that operate currency boards or participate in currency unions have no
monetary or fiscal autonomy. For this reason, fixed exchange rates can be thought of as “soft
pegs,” in contrast to the “hard peg” offered by a currency board or union. But compared to a
country with a floating exchange rate, the ability of a country with a fixed exchange rate to pursue
domestic goals is highly limited. If a currency became overvalued relative to the country to which
it was pegged, then capital would flow out of the country, and the central bank would lose
reserves. When reserves are exhausted and the central bank can no longer meet the demand for
foreign currency, devaluation ensues, if it has not already occurred before events reach this 20
point. The typical reason for a fixed exchange rate to be abandoned in crisis is due to an
unwillingness by the government to abandon domestic goals in favor of defending the exchange
rate. Interest rates can almost always be increased to a point where capital no longer flows out of
the country, but a great contraction in the economy may accompany those rate increases. It is not
uncommon to see interest rates reach triple digits at the height of an exchange rate crisis. Crises
ensue because investors do not believe that the government will have the political will to accept
the economic hardship required to maintain those interest rates in defense of the currency.
As with a hard peg, a fixed exchange rate has the advantage of promoting international trade and
investment by eliminating exchange rate risk. Because the arrangement may be viewed by market
participants as less permanent than a currency board, however, it may generate less trade and
investment.
As with a hard peg, the drawback of a fixed exchange rate compared to floating exchange rates is
that the government has less scope to use monetary and fiscal policy to promote domestic
economic stability. Thus, it leaves countries unable to defend themselves against idiosyncratic
shocks not shared by the country to which it has fixed its currency. As explained above, this is
less of a problem than with a hard peg because imperfect capital mobility does allow for some
deviation from the policy of the country or countries to which you are linked. But the shock
would need to be temporary in nature because a significant deviation could not last.

(...continued)
would hold only about one-fourth of his wealth in American assets and about three-fourths in foreign assets because the
U.S. economy accounts for that fraction of the world economy. Likewise, foreigners would hold one-fourth of their
wealth in American assets and three-fourths abroad. In reality, Americans hold only about one-tenth of their wealth in
foreign assets.
20 The problem is asymmetric. If a fixed exchange rate became undervalued, then capital would flow into the country
and the central bank would accumulate reserves. As long as the central bank is willing to increase its foreign reserves,
an undervalued exchange rate can be sustained. This is believed to be the case with China in recent years.





The scope for the pursuit of domestic goals is greater for countries that fix their exchange rate to a
basket of currencies—unlike a hard peg, the country is no longer placed at the mercy of the
unique and idiosyncratic policies and shocks of any one foreign country. One method for creating
a currency basket is to compose it of the currencies of the country’s primary trading partners,
particularly if the partner has a hard currency, with shares set in proportion to each country’s
proportion of trade. If the correlation of the business cycle with each trading partner is
proportional to the share of trade with that country, then the potential for idiosyncratic shocks to
harm the economy should be considerably reduced when pegged to a basket of currencies. On the
down side, baskets do not encourage any more bilateral trade and investment than a floating
exchange rate because they reintroduce bilateral exchange rate risk with each trading partner.
There is a popular perception that the advantage of a fixed exchange rate is that it allows
countries to set their exchange rate below market value in order to boost exports and curb 21
imports. For example, this claim is often leveled against China. Economists would disagree that
an artificially low exchange rate is in a country’s self interest. Although it has the benefit of
boosting a country’s trade balance, it also has costs. By making imports more expensive, it
reduces consumers’ purchasing power. And by distorting market signals, it funnels resources
away from their most efficient use. Finally, an undervalued exchange rate confers no permanent
trade advantage because it will eventually cause domestic prices to rise, canceling out the price
advantage offered by the exchange rate.
In previous decades, it was believed that developing countries with a profligate past could bolster
a new commitment to macroeconomic credibility through the use of a fixed exchange rate for two
reasons. First, for countries with inflation rates that were previously very high, the maintenance
of fixed exchange rates would act as a signal to market participants that inflation was now under
control. For example, inflation causes the number of dollars that can be bought with one peso to
decline just as it causes the number of apples that can be bought with one peso to decline. Thus, a
fixed exchange rate can only be maintained if large inflation differentials are eliminated. Second,
a fixed exchange rate was thought to anchor inflationary expectations by providing stable import
prices. For a given change in monetary policy, economy theory suggests that inflation will decline
faster if people expect lower inflation.
After the many crises involving fixed exchange rate regimes in the 1980s and 1990s, this
argument has become less persuasive. Unlike a currency board, a fixed exchange rate regime does 22
nothing concrete to tie policymakers’ hands and prevent a return to bad macroeconomic policy.
Resisting the temptation to finance budget deficits through inflation ultimately depends on
political will; if the political will is lacking, then the exchange rate regime will be abandoned, as
was the case in many 1980s exchange rate crises. Thus burnt in the past, investors may no longer
see a fixed exchange rate as a credible commitment by the government to macroeconomic
stability, reducing the benefits of the fixed exchange rate. Furthermore, some currency board
proponents claim that this lack of credibility means that investors will “test” the government’s
commitment to maintaining a soft peg in ways that are costly to the economy. By contrast, they

21 See CRS Report RS21625, China’s Currency: A Summary of the Economic Issues, by Wayne M. Morrison and Marc
Labonte.
22 In this light, soft pegs based on a basket of currencies are typically viewed as a less transparent arrangement
involving less political commitment to maintaining discipline than a soft peg based on a single currency.





claim that investors will not test a currency board because they have no doubt of the
government’s commitment.
For this reason, many economists who previously recommended fixed exchange rates on the basis
of their political merits have shifted in recent years towards support of a hard peg. This has been
dubbed the “bipolar view” of exchange rate regimes: growing international capital mobility has
made the world economy behave more similarly to what models have suggested. As capital flows
become more responsive to interest rate differentials, the ability of “soft peg” fixed exchange rate
regimes to simultaneously pursue domestic policy goals and maintain the exchange rate has
become untenable. As a result, countries are being pushed toward floating exchange rates (the
freedom to pursue domestic goals) or “hard pegs” (policy directed solely toward maintaining the
exchange rate). In this view, while “soft pegs” may have been successful in the past, any attempt
by a country open to international capital to maintain a soft peg today is likely to end in an
exchange rate crisis, as happened to Mexico, the countries of Southeast Asia, Brazil, and Turkey.
Empirically, the trend does appear to be moving in this direction. In 1991, 65% of the world’s 55
largest economies used “soft peg” exchange rate arrangements; in 1999, the number had fallen to 23

27%.


Although the international trend has been towards greater capital mobility and openness, it should
be pointed out that there are still developing countries that are not open to capital flows. The
“bipolar view” argument may not hold for these countries: without capital flows reacting to
changes in interest rates, these countries may be capable of maintaining a soft peg and an
independent monetary policy.
For a fixed exchange rate to work, the relative supply and demand for a country’s currency must
remain stable over time, or the government must adjust the value at which the exchange rate is
fixed whenever supply and demand significantly change. In practice, the primary problem with
fixed exchange rates has been that countries have faced frequent changes in economic conditions
that put pressure on the fixed exchange rate to change, but countries have proven unwilling to
change the exchange rate promptly. (Of course, frequent changes undermine many of the
economic and political rationales for using fixed exchange rates.) Some countries have faced
economic pressures to raise the value of the exchange rate, others to lower it. An undervalued
exchange rate can be maintained indefinitely, as long as the country is willing to accumulate
foreign exchange reserves. But it may lead to political tensions with trading partners, as has been
the case recently between China and the United States. When the exchange rate is overvalued, it
frequently results in economic crisis, as will be discussed in the next section.


The previous discussion summarizes the textbook advantages and disadvantages of different
exchange rate regimes. As such, it abstracts and simplifies from many economic issues that may
bear directly on real policymaking. In particular, it neglects the possibility that crisis could be
caused or transmitted through international goods or capital markets, and the transmission role

23 Stanley Fischer, “Exchange Rate Regimes: Is the Bipolar View Correct?” Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 15,
no. 2, spring 2001, p. 9.





exchange rates can play in crisis. The remainder of the report will be devoted to trying to glean
some general lessons from the international crises of the 1990s, which featured rapidly falling
exchange rates and asset prices, international capital flight, and financial unrest, to enrich our
understanding of how different exchange rate regimes function. The primary lesson seems to be
that fixed exchange rate regimes are prone to crisis, while a crisis caused by international capital
movements is extremely improbable under floating regimes. Unlike the crises of the 1980s, most
of the countries involved in 1990s crises—particularly Southeast Asia—had relatively good
macroeconomic policies in place (e.g., low inflation, balanced budgets, relatively free capital
mobility). Thus, these crises cannot be blamed simply on policy errors.
Fixed exchange rate regimes are The primary lesson of the 1990s seems to be that fixed exchange rate
prone to crisis because investors are regimes are prone to crisis, while crisis is extremely improbable under
compelled to remove their money floating regimes.


from a country before it devalues. It
is similar to a fire in a crowded theater: although everyone easily entered the theater in an orderly
fashion, if everyone tries to rush out at once, the doors jam and the fire becomes a catastrophe.
Proponents of fixed exchange rate regimes often argue that they can be adjusted if they “get out
of line.” But the weakness of fixed exchange rate regimes is that when economic fundamentals
change in such a way that devaluation becomes necessary, there is no mechanism to devalue
except crisis. Even if a government wanted to announce a planned devaluation to avoid crisis, the
announcement would likely spur anticipatory capital flight as investors tried to withdraw their
investments before the new exchange rate was implemented.
Corruption, “crony capitalism,” and “greedy speculation” are not needed to explain why fixed
exchange rates collapse. The countries forced to devalue during the Asian Crisis (Thailand,
Malaysia, Philippines, Indonesia, and South Korea) had very different economic structures and
political systems, and were at different stages of economic development, ranging from a per 24
capita GDP of $15,355 in South Korea to $4,111 in Indonesia. What they all had in common
was their exchange rate peg to the U.S. dollar. The Asian crisis was instigated by the fact that the
appreciating U.S. dollar, to which the crisis countries were fixed, had made their exports less
competitive and encouraged imports, particularly compared to China (which had devalued its
exchange rate in 1994) and Japan.
Investment bubbles, notably in property markets, seemed to be present in all of the crisis
countries, although there is no accepted method to identify them even after the fact. Some argue
that the bursting of these bubbles played a key role in instigating the crises. Theories for why the
bubbles formed include widespread state allocation of capital, poor local financial regulation, and
simple misguided exuberance on the part of investors. Whether the bursting of such a bubble
could have instigated the crisis under a floating exchange rate is debatable. Some sharp declines
in asset prices have sparked serious crises and downturns, as was the case in Japan in the early
1990s. Other times, sharp asset price declines have not caused crisis and have had little lasting
effect on the economy, as was the case with the United States in 1987. But what is clear is that an
asset bubble and a fixed exchange rate can interact in ways more virulent than their individual
parts. To the extent that asset prices would have fallen in Asia to return to their fundamental
levels anyway, the presence of a fixed exchange rate ensured that it would happen suddenly
because of the “fire in a theater” principle. To the extent that a devaluation would have been

24 At purchasing power parity in 1997, before the crisis. Source: DRI-WEFA.



necessary anyway, the presence of an asset bubble assured that the outflows would be larger,
placing more of a strain on the countries’ financial systems.
Figure 1. Exchange Rates of Asian Crisis Countries
Source: International Monetary Fund, International Financial Statistics, (Washington: March 2000).
Note: Exchange rates are the market bilateral dollar exchange rate measured at the end of the quarter.
When investors recognize a situation where devaluation becomes likely, even though they may
have had no intention of leaving a country otherwise, they have every incentive to remove their
money before the devaluation occurs because devaluation makes the local investment worth less
in foreign currency. Because the central bank’s reserves will always be smaller than liquid capital
flows when capital is mobile, devaluation becomes inevitable when investors lose faith in the
government’s willingness to correct the exchange rate’s misalignment. To an extent, the
phenomenon then takes on the aspect of a self-fulfilling prophecy. The reason the depreciation of
a currency in crisis is typically so dramatic is because at that point investors are no longer leaving
because of economic fundamentals, but simply to avoid being the one “standing when the music
stops.”
Notice that in the textbook explanation, a currency depreciation is expected to boost growth
through an improved trade balance. In a currency crisis, this does not happen at first, although it
does happen eventually, because resources cannot be reallocated towards increased exports
quickly enough to compensate for the blow to the economy that comes through the sudden
withdrawal of capital. In the Asian crisis, businessmen told of export orders they were unable to
fill following devaluation because their credit line had been withdrawn.





The shock of the capital outflow is exacerbated by the tendency for banking systems to become
unbalanced in fixed exchange rate regimes. When foreigners lending to the banking system start
to doubt the sustainability of an exchange rate regime, they tend to shift exchange rate risk from
themselves to the banking system in two ways. First, foreign investors denominate their lending
in their own currency, so that the financial loss caused by devaluation is borne by the banking
system. Before devaluation, a bank’s assets might exceed its liabilities. With devaluation, the
foreign currency liabilities suddenly multiply in value with the stroke of a pen without any 25
physical change in the economy, and the banks become insolvent. Second, foreign lending to the
banking system is done on a short-term basis so that investments can be repatriated before
devaluation takes place. This is problematic because most of a bank’s investments are longer
term. The banks then enter a cycle where the short-term debt is rolled over until crisis strikes, at
which point credit lines are cut. Both of these factors lead to a situation where a currency crisis
causes a banking crisis, which is a much more significant barrier to economic recovery than the
devaluation itself. These two characteristics both tend to be present when lending to developing
countries even in good times; the tendencies are accelerated when booms look unsustainable. An
exception may have been Brazil, which some economists have suggested recovered so quickly
from its devaluation because its banking system had few short-term, foreign currency 26
denominated assets.
It is not necessarily illogical for the banking system to accept financing on a short term basis or
denominated in foreign currency when credit conditions tighten. If it did not accept all forms of
financing available to it, it could face insolvency at worst and a significant contraction in business
at best. If the banks believe that the downturn is temporary and the episode will pass without a
currency devaluation, then the banks will be able to repay the loans once conditions improve. If
devaluation causes them to fail, they may expect the government to bail them out, perhaps
explaining their willingness to accept these currency risks.
These factors make it clear that once Once a country enters a currency crisis, there is no policy response that can
a country enters a currency crisis, avoid significant economic dislocation.


there is no policy response that can
avoid significant economic dislocation. A policy to lower interest rates to boost aggregate demand
and add liquidity to the financial system causes the currency to devalue further, increasing the
capital outflow and exacerbating the banking system’s insolvency. A policy to raise interest rates
in support of the currency exacerbates the economic downturn brought on by crisis by reducing
investment demand further. This too can feed through to the banking system and capital markets
by bankrupting significant portions of the private sector. And it may not quell the currency crisis.
In a textbook analysis, interest rates can always be increased to attract back the capital leaving. In
reality, after a certain point higher interest rates increase default risk, perhaps causing more 27
capital flight than lower interest rates would bring.
Both the Mexican crisis and the East Asian crisis were exacerbated by contagion effects where
crisis spread from country to country in the region. This cannot be explained by an irrational (and

25 The insolvency problem occurs because, in practice, the bank does not denominate its assets in terms of the foreign
currency. This is presumably because its assets are domestic loans.
26 Paul Krugman, “Crises: The Price of Globalization? paper presented at Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City
symposium, August 2000.
27 Jason Furman and Joseph Stiglitz, “Economic Crises: Evidence and Insights from East Asia, Brookings Papers on
Economic Activity 2, Brookings Institution (Washington: 1998), p. 1.



degrading) assumption by investors that “all Asians/South Americans are crooks.” Rather, it
reflects the regional interdependence of these economies. Although there is no a priori evidence
that South Korea’s currency was overvalued, it became overvalued once its neighbors were forced
to devalue. That is because its exports competed with its neighbors, and exports accounted for a
large fraction of its GDP. After its neighbors devalued, South Korean exporters, already
struggling because the Japanese yen had been depreciating, could no longer offer competitive
prices. Simultaneously, it appears that investors’ perception of the riskiness of emerging markets
in general greatly increased, curtailing lending to South Korea, which placed pressure on interest 28
rates and investment. At this point, the deterioration in economic fundamentals caused the
Korean won to become overvalued, and currency crisis spread.
One may ask why the Bretton Woods fixed exchange rate system that fixed the currencies of the
major western economies from 1945 to 1971 was not prone to crisis (at least before it collapsed). 29
The reason is that capital mobility was largely curtailed under the Bretton Woods system.
Without capital mobility, central banks could use their reserves to accommodate small changes in
fundamentals and could respond to large changes in fundamentals with a (relatively) orderly
devaluation. As long as capital remains mobile—and almost nobody has supported a return to
permanent capital controls—the Bretton Woods arrangement cannot be replicated. It was not long
after capital controls were removed that the Bretton Woods system experienced a growing
number of currency crises in the 1960s and 1970s, leading to its eventual demise.
Some economists argue that if short-term, foreign-currency denominated debt is the real culprit in
recent crises, then it makes more sense to address the problem directly, rather than through the
indirect approach of making it more costly through a floating exchange rate. The problem could
be addressed directly through various forms of capital controls, financial regulations, or taxes on
capital flows. They argue that capital controls are necessary until financial markets become well
enough developed to cope with sudden capital inflows and outflows. Capital controls would also
allow countries to operate an independent monetary policy while maintaining the trade-related
benefits of a fixed exchange rate, similar to how the Bretton Woods system operated. Yet capital
controls deter capital inflows as well as capital outflows, and rapid development is difficult
without capital inflows. Capital controls may make crises less likely, but they are also likely to
reduce a country’s long run sustainable growth rate.
That is not to argue that floating exchange rates are stable and predictable, as some economists
claimed they would be before their adoption in the 1970s. Rather, it is to argue that their volatility
has very little effect on the macroeconomy. For example, the South African rand lost half of its
value against the U.S. dollar between 1999 and 2001. Yet GDP growth averaged 2.8% and
inflation averaged 5.4% in those years. To be sure, when exchange rates change their value by a
significant amount in a few years, exporting and import-competing sectors of the economy suffer.
Manufacturing and farming are among those sectors in the United States. But there is very little
evidence to suggest that in a well-balanced economy such as the United States, other sectors of
the economy cannot pick up the slack when the currency appreciates, especially when monetary
policy is applied prudently. The one-third appreciation of the dollar and record trade deficits

28 Foreign portfolio investment in Korea fell from an inflow of $12,287 million in 1996 to an outflow of $2,086 million
in the fourth quarter of 1997, while foreign lending to banks fell from an inflow of $9,952 million in 1996 to an outflow
of $6,125 million in the fourth quarter of 1997.
29Most countries in Europe did not restore (currency) convertibility until the end of 1958, with Japan following in
1964.... The restoration of convertibility did not result in immediate and complete international financial integration....”
Paul Krugman and Maurice Obstfeld, International Economics, Addison-Wesley (Reading, MA: 1997), p. 551.





between 1995 and 2000 did not prevent the U.S. economy from achieving stellar growth and
unemployment that at one point dipped below 4%. While floating exchange rates sometimes
move by substantial amounts in a couple of years, they do not move by substantial amounts
overnight, as happens in fixed exchange rate crises. And that is the key reason why floating
exchange rates are not prone to financial and economic crises.
Floating and fixed exchange rates both impose costs on economies. Floating exchange rates
impose a cost by discouraging trade and investment. Fixed exchange rates impose a cost by
limiting policymakers’ ability to pursue domestic stabilization, thereby making the economy less
stable. But there is a fundamental difference in the types of costs they impose. In most countries,
the cost of floating exchange rates is internalized and can be managed through the market in the 30
form of hedging. (Developing countries with undeveloped financial systems may not be able to
adequately hedge exchange rate risk, however.) Part of the cost of fixed exchange rates is an
externality and cannot be hedged away. In other words, society as a whole bears some of the costs
of fixed exchange rate regimes, so that market participants do not take that cost into account in
their transactions. The costs that society bears are threefold. First, to the extent that a country
faces unique shocks to its economy, it gives up the ability to protect its economy against these
shocks. Those involved in international trade and investment do not compensate society at large
for the fact that the volatility of aggregate unemployment and inflation has been increased.
Second, the fixed exchange rate regime is more prone to crisis, which further increases the
probability of high unemployment episodes. Even if floating exchange rates were to lead to lower
growth because they dampen the growth of trade and foreign investment, risk averse individuals
may prefer that outcome if it leads to fewer crises. Third, in some historical instances, fixed
exchange rates have weakened the banking system through their incentives to take on debt that
cannot be repaid in the event of devaluation. Of the three factors, the last is the only one that
could theoretically be rectified through regulation, although implementing such regulation in
practice could be difficult, particularly in the developing world.
This is not to argue that fixed exchange rate regimes are never superior to floating regimes. The
United States would not be better off with 50 separate currencies for each state even though it
would ameliorate regional recessions. When countries economies are interdependent enough, the
benefits of fixed exchange rates outweigh the costs: regions experience fewer unique shocks,
labor mobility improves, product markets may benefit from greater competition and economies of
scale, and capital market integration increases. But few countries meet this criterion. Whether the
countries of the euro zone become interdependent enough to make the euro sustainable remains to
be seen. At the time the euro was introduced, growth between the “core” (countries like Germany
and Italy) and the “periphery” (countries like Ireland and Finland) were widely divergent,
although they seem to have narrowed since the euro was introduced.
But many developing countries that have adopted (or have considered adopting) fixed exchange
rates are not well integrated with the economy to which they are linked (see Appendix). That is
because these countries are looking to link to the world’s major “hard” currencies, the U.S. dollar,
the euro, the Japanese yen, the British pound, or the Swiss franc. Because they are often choosing
to fix their exchange rate to gain credibility (e.g., after an episode of high inflation), only a hard
currency would provide that credibility. But because the economies of most developing countries
are not closely tied to these hard currency economies, they are likely to face very different

30 If floating exchange rates do fluctuate irrationally as some economists have posited, this imposes another cost on an
economy, a cost that can be eliminated with no sacrifice by a fixed exchange rate.





economic shocks from the hard currency economy. Therefore, they will not be able to adjust
policy in response to the shock because of the fixed exchange, nor will they receive any policy
adjustment from the country they are fixed to, because the hard currency country, facing no
shock, has no need to adjust its policy. This makes these countries more prone to boom and bust
than they would be with a (responsibly run) floating exchange rate. Certainly, Russia and the
countries of East Asia and Latin America that were struck by currency crises in the 1990s were
not closely enough integrated with the U.S. economy to make a dollar peg sustainable. Of these
countries, only Mexico and the Philippines experienced growth that was positively correlated
with U.S. growth in the 1990s.
Proponents of currency boards argue that they do not suffer the vulnerabilities of traditional fixed
exchange rates because devaluation becomes too costly an option for the government to consider.
For that reason, they argue, investors have no qualms about the safety of their money, and
speculators know they cannot undermine the currency, so they do not try. The example of 31
Argentina’s currency board demonstrates why this argument is unpersuasive. In making this
argument, currency board proponents are only focusing on the political advantage to a currency
board—it makes profligate fiscal and monetary policy impossible. But this is not the only factor
that makes economies grow and investors choose them as an investment location. A currency
board eliminates currency risk, but it does nothing to eliminate a country’s macroeconomic risk,
to which investors are just as sensitive. For example, there are good reasons why the overall U.S.
economy would not be significantly affected by the dollar’s one-third appreciation since 1995,
but there is no reason why the Argentine economy would be unaffected. It had not received the
large capital inflows or experienced the rapid economic growth that made the dollar’s
appreciation sustainable—some would argue, desirable—for the United States despite its
implication for exporters. Thus, Argentine’s exporters and import-competing industries became
uncompetitive in the last five years with no countervailing factors to make other sectors of the
economy competitive. In fact, developments to the Argentine economy suggest a floating
exchange rate would have naturally depreciated in recent years to offset negative factors. The
prices of commodities (which are important exports for Argentina) had been falling, foreign
investment to developing nations had fallen since the Asian crisis, and Argentina’s largest trading
partner, Brazil, underwent a significant devaluation in 1998. Although the currency board may
have lowered political risk in Argentina, for these reasons, it greatly increased macroeconomic
risk, and that is why the currency board collapsed in 2002. In the face of macroeconomic risk and
political upheaval, Argentina proved that no currency arrangement is permanent.
It is beyond the scope of this report to explore the question of whether developing countries with
a profligate economic past can make a credible new start without fixing their exchange rates.
Some economists go farther and suggest that in today’s globalized economy, fixed exchange rates
are no longer viable, and adopting a foreign currency becomes necessary for a country trying to
make a new start. In those few cases where a natural currency union partner already exists, a
fixed exchange rate offers considerable economic advantages, particularly for a country trying to
overcome a profligate past. For all other countries, after considering the experience of recent
years, the economic advantages to floating exchange rates seem considerable.

31 For more information on the Argentine economy, see CRS Report RL31169, Argentina: Economic Problems and
Solutions, by Gail E. Makinen.







The statement that some international economies are naturally suited for floating exchange rate
regimes while some economies are naturally suited for a fixed exchange rate with a major trading
partner is an uncontroversial statement among economists. It is based on the insights first
provided by economist Robert Mundell’s model of an optimum currency area, which outlines the 32
criteria that determine under what circumstances a fixed exchange rate would succeed. This
model underlines the discussion of advantages and disadvantages presented in the first part of this
report. Controversy arises among economists on two points. First, it arises on the political
question of how important the political benefits of fixed exchange rates should be, which cannot
be addressed by the model. Second, it arises from the fact that the empirical parameters of the
optimum currency area model are not well established, with economists disagreeing about how
much integration is actually needed for a fixed exchange rate to succeed.
This appendix attempts to offer some empirical evidence on the latter question. It approximates a
country’s interdependence with its largest trading partner based on two key criteria from the
optimum currency area model:
• How closely linked the two countries are through trade, measured as exports to the
trading partner as a percentage of total exports in 2005.
• The degree of correlation between the two countries’ business cycles, measured as 33
correlation of economic growth from 1997 to 2006.
The results are presented for selected developed countries and areas in Table A-1.
Using any specific cutoff point to define two economies as interdependent vs. independent for
either measure would be arbitrary, but some countries do not achieve even the bare minimum of
interdependence. Negative growth correlation means that, overall, the business cycle in the
largest trading partner was typically moving in the opposite direction of the country for any given
year in the sample. Typically, this would put pressure on their exchange rates to move in opposite
directions as well. Similarly, it would be difficult to argue that the largest trading partner was
closely tied to the country economic well-being if it did not receive a large share of the country’s
exports.

32 Robert Mundell,A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas, American Economic Review, vol. 51, September 1961,
pp. 657-665.
33 Correlation is a measure of the typical relationship in the movement of two variables. It is measured such that
correlation equals −1 when the variables move in exactly opposite direction, equals 0 when there is no relationship in
the movement of the two variables, and equals 1 when the variables move in exactly the same direction.





Table A-1. Economic Interdependence of Selected Developed Countries and Hong
Kong
Exports to Largest Correlation of Growth with
Country Largest Trading Partner Partner (as % total Largest Partner
exports)
Australia Japan 20% -.53
Canada U.S. 82% .75
Denmark euro area 45% .73
Hong Kong China 45% .53
New Zealand Australia 22% -.07
Norway euro area 44% .50
Singapore Malaysia 14% .86
Sweden euro area 44% .69
Switzerland euro area 51% .82
United Kingdom euro area 48% .78
Source: International Monetary Fund, World Economic Outlook Database and Direction of Trade Statistics.
Note: Export data are for 2005; correlation is between 1997-2006. All countries in the table maintain a floating
exchange rate regime except for Hong Kong, which operates a currency board, and Denmark, which operates a
fixed exchange rate.
By these measures, of the countries in Table A-1, Australia and New Zealand seem poorly suited
for a fixed exchange rate on both measures. Both countries are relatively physically isolated and
not overly reliant on any particular trading partner. A case could be made for a fixed exchange
rate for the other countries in the table; a strong case could be made for Canada and 34
Switzerland.
But a closer look at Canada suggests that a successful floating exchange rate may not be
incompatible even with a country as closely interdependent with its neighbor as Canada is with
the United States. Despite its interdependence, Canada has maintained robust growth and low
inflation with a floating exchange rate. Because commodities are a larger percentage of its output
than that of the United States, its economy responds to changes in commodity prices differently
than the United States does. As a result, its currency has appreciated as commodity prices have
risen.

34 Hong Kong maintains a currency board with the United States, although China is its largest trading partner. Because
China’s exchange rate is kept relatively constant against the dollar, however, a currency board with the dollar is nearly
the same as maintaining one with the Chinese yuan.





Marc Labonte
Specialist in Macroeconomic Policy
mlabonte@crs.loc.gov, 7-0640