Dividend Tax Relief: Effects on Economic Recovery, Long-Term Growth, and the Stock Market








Prepared for Members and Committees of Congress



Several objectives were advanced for the President’s 2003 proposal for dividend relief to
eliminate double taxation of corporate source income, including “creating jobs” (suggestive of a
short-run stimulative effect), enhancing long-term growth and efficiency, “fairness,” and
increasing the value of the stock market. Dividend relief was enacted on a temporary basis in

2003 and was extended in 2006. Elimination of the tax is a focus of some tax reform proposals.


Dividend relief was not considered in 2008.
Short-run stimulus objectives often conflict with long-run growth because an increase in spending
is needed to stimulate an underemployed economy in the short run while an increase in saving (or
labor supply) is needed to increase long-run growth. Dividend relief proposal is less likely to
stimulate short-run demand than a spending increase or some other tax cuts because it accrues to
higher income individuals who may save a larger fraction of the cut. It is also unlikely that this
saving effect will be quickly translated into investment spending; indeed dividend relief could
decrease spending by shifting assets out of direct investment in unincorporated business assets
and housing and into financial assets.
The longer-run growth effects of the dividend proposal (financed by debt and measured as
changes in standard of living) are likely negative and would become quite large over time if debt
financed. This analysis finds that reductions of -0.16% to -0.10% would occur after 10 years, with
-0.39% to -0.22% after 20 years. Only very large savings elasticities well out of the range of
empirical evidence could induce growth that offsets deficit effects. Positive growth effects may
occur if the cut is offset by spending cuts and the savings elasticity positive, but such effects are
small and require a quick spending decrease. In one simulation, a tax cut which increased the
deficit for 10 years induced negative output effects for over 30 years.
Economic analysis would reject a “fairness” argument across investors because of reallocation of
capital. However, reallocation is the key to achieving efficiency gains that are the main benefit of
the dividend relief proposal.
The effects on the stock market are likely to be small, with an upper limit of 5% to 6%, but
probably much less due to changes in interest rates and expectations of adjustment. Changes on
the order of 2% to 3% may be more likely. Any stock market effects represent temporary
windfalls to holders of current stocks and are simply a manifestation of the income effects of the
tax cut; these wealth effects should not be considered as an additional stimulus. There is little
evidence of general effects on spending through consumer confidence and the effect is quite small
to function as a signal.
Recent studies finding that dividends had increased substantially have been used to argue that the
tax cut induced private savings. This evidence does not appear robust and, even if dividends
increased, there are no obvious consequences for savings. This report describes basic economic
relationships and will not be updated.






Short-Run Stimulus and Long-Term Growth..................................................................................1
Short Run..................................................................................................................................1
Long-Run Growth.....................................................................................................................2
Effects of Savings Elasticities.............................................................................................3
Effects of Labor Supply and Factor Substitution Elasticities.............................................4
Conditions Favorable to Positive Effects............................................................................4
International Capital Inflows..............................................................................................5
Neoclassical Growth Versus Life Cycle Model..................................................................5
Overall Effects on Growth..................................................................................................6
Reallocation of Capital (Portfolio Effects)......................................................................................6
Tax Exempt Shareholders and Tax Preference Passthrough Limits................................................7
The Stock Market............................................................................................................................8
An Overview of Economic Issues.............................................................................................9
Estimated Stock Market Effects: A Standard Analysis............................................................10
Cost of the Tax Cut...........................................................................................................10
Discount Factor..................................................................................................................11
Stock Market Value............................................................................................................11
Method of Calculation......................................................................................................12
The Trapped Equity or “New” View of Dividends.................................................................13
Did the 2003 Tax Cut Increase Dividends and What are the Implications?..................................15
Evidence on the Dividend Response.......................................................................................16
What Does it Mean for Saving?..............................................................................................17
Conclusion ..................................................................................................................................... 18
Growth Model.........................................................................................................................19
Adjustment and the Stock Market Value.................................................................................20
The Trapped Equity or New View of Dividends.....................................................................21
Table 1. Percentage Increase in Income Available for Consumption from Dividend Relief,
Depending on the Size of the Savings Elasticity (E), Growth Model..........................................3
Table 2. Percentage Increase in Income Available for Consumption: Sensitivity to Labor
Supply (λ) and Factor Substitution (S) Elasticities......................................................................4
Table 3. Percentage Increase in Income Available for Consumption, Effects of Large
Savings Elasticities (E) and Deficit Offsets via Spending Cuts...................................................5
Table 4. Percentage Increase in Income Available for Consumption, Effects of
International Capital Flows..........................................................................................................5
Table 5. Personal Dividend Income...............................................................................................16





Appendix. Underlying Calculations..............................................................................................19
Author Contact Information..........................................................................................................22





everal objectives were advanced for the President’s proposal for dividend relief to eliminate
double taxation of corporate source income, including “creating jobs” (which is suggestive
of a short-run stimulative effect), enhancing long-term growth and efficiency, “fairness,” S


and increasing the value of the stock market. This report discusses these effects. After providing a
general analysis of the effects of tax cuts on short- and long-run growth, the paper discusses three
additional aspects of the proposed dividend revision: reallocation of capital (and its implications
for fairness and efficiency), tax exempt investments and preference passthrough restrictions, and
the role of the stock market.
Dividend relief was enacted in 2003 in the Jobs and Growth Tax Reconciliation Act (P.L. 108-27)
and extended in the Tax Increase Prevention and Reconciliation Act (P.L. 109-222) in 2006. The
enacted version did not contain the preference passthrough limits, but only partially cut dividend
taxes by lowering the rate to 15%. It also reduced capital gains tax rates to the same level. These
offsetting effects left the final version similar in overall magnitude to the President’s proposal,
although having somewhat different features. The analysis of the stimulus, growth, and efficiency
effects, performed originally for the President’s proposal, should also reflect the general effects of
the final enacted proposal, presuming the tax cuts are expected to become permanent.

One of the confusing aspects of economic policy is that policies that are effective for short-term
stimulus purposes tend to reduce long-term growth. Spending promotes short-run growth; saving
promotes long-term growth. It is particularly hard to devise an individual tax cut that can
accomplish its short-run purpose effectively without undermining long-term growth, absent some
other future policy. And, while there may be circumstances where fiscal stimulus is desirable (i.e.,
when interest rates are extremely low initially or a contraction is severe), many economists feel
that the primary tool of economic stabilization should be monetary policy. This view is reinforced
by the leakage of fiscal stimulus (but not monetary stimulus) that occurs in an open economy.
In the short run, to stimulate the economy through fiscal policy requires an increase in
spending—on consumption, on investment, or on government purchases. The most direct way to
accomplish this effect is through spending by the government. Spending increases add to the
deficit and reduce the capital stock which can be harmful to long-run growth, but if the spending
increase is temporary, this effect will be small. The major problem with spending is that spending
programs are often difficult to agree upon and put into place in a timely fashion (although if
cutbacks are already planned, a delay of the cutbacks would be relatively easy). Emergency
spending can also be wasteful, and it may be difficult to reverse the spending increase in the
future once groups have a stake in it.
Nevertheless, stimulating the economy through increasing private incomes (through transfers or
tax cuts) is likely to be less effective and more problematic than spending increases for two
reasons. First, there is at least some reason to believe that much of a temporary tax cut will not be
spent initially, but rather will be spread over a long period of time. Permanent tax cuts or
transfers, which may be more successful in inducing spending, add to the deficit every year, and
so reduce the long-run accumulation of capital. Reversing purportedly permanent tax cuts after
granting them undermines the belief that tax cuts will be permanent and interferes with their



future effectiveness. Secondly, individuals are likely to save some fraction of income (even
permanent income) and saving does not increase aggregate demand. This effect is, however,
probably not very important. Both of these problems are likely to be less serious with transfers or
with tax cuts directed at lower income individuals, who are more likely to be liquidity constrained
in their spending (and thus would spend all the tax cut) and who tend to have lower savings rates.
In these cases tax cuts, particularly temporary ones, are likely to be more effective if directed at
lower income individuals.
One of the potential ways to provide tax cuts that are effective stimulants without undermining
long-run growth through deficit financing is to provide investment incentives to firms. If firms
directly increase their investment in response to a tax cut, the induced private investment expands
demand in the short run and also offsets the reduction in the capital stock. Tax subsidies for
investment may not, however, work very well if firms with excess capacity (typical in a sluggish
economy) cannot be easily encouraged to spend. In this case, however, a temporary tax cut is
actually more effective than a permanent one because it encourages firms to accelerate their
capital investment program. Such a temporary tax cut (bonus depreciation) was enacted in 2002.
How does dividend tax relief—and specifically a provision that provides a dividend exclusion
and future capital gains exclusion for earnings retained—fit into this standard analysis? As a
permanent provision, it is more likely to result in a stimulus. Dividend relief tends to be directed
at relatively high income individuals who are less likely to spend, so it might be somewhat less
effective than tax cuts aimed at lower income individuals. If the tax cut induces an increase in the
savings rate, the stimulative effect would be smaller (although the effect on the savings rate could
go either way, as discussed below). Nor is the tax cut likely to be very effective at inducing
investment spending by a firm for several reasons. First, the incentive is provided to the
individual who receives the benefit rather than the firm; this approach results in a more indirect
route to investment stimulus. Second, even if the firm responds quickly on behalf of its
shareholders, this type of tax cut largely benefits earnings from existing capital and is one of the 1
least effective tax cuts for encouraging investment spending. Finally, as discussed below in the
section on portfolio shifts, the reallocation effects of the relief could actually contract investment
spending in the short run.
In the long run, the dividend relief proposal will succeed in increasing output and growth (other
than the modest effects associated with economic efficiency) only if it increases personal saving 2
by more than the revenue cost and accumulating interest on the debt. It is theoretically possible
for this effect to occur initially, but most evidence does not support a large savings response to tax
rate changes. Indeed, some evidence suggests that savings can fall as the rate of return rises (due
to wealth effects). Even large savings responses would eventually result in a deteriorating capital

1 A permanent investment stimulus (e.g., accelerated depreciation) would be more effective than a rate cut per dollar of
revenue loss because a rate reduction provides more of its benefits for returns to the existing capital stock. A temporary
investment stimulus would be more effective still, but a temporary rate cut could have perverse effects because it could
actually increase effective tax burdens on new investment by reducing the value of accelerated depreciation.
2 In an open economy government borrowing may be offset by foreign net capital inflows. However, that additional
capital cannot contribute to the future standard of living of Americans other than in a minor way because it and its
returns are owned by foreigners. Note also that the dividend exclusion plan does not apply to foreign shareholders and
thus provides no incentive for increases in foreign equity investment in the U.S.; however, the provision does provide
incentives for equity investment abroad by U.S. firms.





stock because debt and the interest on debt would compound. Thus, the dividend relief proposal
would harm long-run growth as long as it is based on deficit finance.
To demonstrate the magnitude and potential direction of these growth effects, we use a
neoclassical growth model with an endogenous savings rate. The details of this model are
presented in the Appendix.
Table 1 shows the projected effects of the proposal for various savings elasticities, for the first,
fifth, tenth, and twentieth year, representing a reasonable span of the empirical evidence on 3
savings elasticities. Small and possibly negative elasticities are also theoretically consistent with
offsetting income and substitution effects: greater wealth from higher rates of return increase
current consumption but a cheaper price of future consumption reduces current consumption.
The estimates assume a fixed labor supply (also consistent with empirical evidence) and a Cobb-
Douglas production function. Rather than considering percentage changes in GDP, a measure
reflecting standard of living effects is used: income available for consumption after accounting
for steady state investment necessary to sustain the capital stock at its current level. This measure 4
could loosely be interpreted as a change in the sustainable standard of living. The percentage
change is similar to the percentage change in output. As Table 1 suggests, the plan’s projected
effects would be to reduce output by a growing amount because the effect of the deficit on
reducing the capital stock is larger than any induced savings response.
In none of these cases is the effect on private saving large enough to offset the contraction in
capital. The effects are actually quite small, an outcome that is not surprising because the
dividend relief proposal is relatively small. The negative effects continue to grow over time as
deficits accumulate, and, eventually, the model “explodes” as deficits displace the entire capital
stock.
Table 1. Percentage Increase in Income Available for Consumption from Dividend
Relief, Depending on the Size of the Savings Elasticity (E), Growth Model
Year E = -0.4E = -0.2 E = 0.0 E = 0.2 E = 0.4
1 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01
5 -0.08 -0.07 -0.06 -0.05 -0.05
10 -0.16 -0.15 -0.13 -0.11 -0.10
20 -0.39 -0.34 -0.30 -0.26 -0.22
Source: CRS calculations, see Appendix. Calculations assume fixed labor supply and factor substitution
elasticity of 1.0.

3 See Eric Engen, Jane G. Gravelle, and Kent Smetters, Dynamic Tax Models: Why They Do the Things They Do,”
National Tax Journal, vol. 50, Sept. 1997, pp. 657-682.
4 This measure also prevents misleading representations from arising from a model where capital is imported. Since
foreign suppliers own the rights to the capital, decreases or increases in capital stock reflecting foreign imports have
limited effects on standards of living because foreigners have the claim to earnings.





Table 2 provides for sensitivity analysis, and shows the effects of allowing labor supply to
respond positively to a higher wage and allowing a smaller factor substitution elasticity (and the
combination). A positive labor supply elasticity magnifies a negative effect (because as the capital
stock falls, the wage rate falls), while a lower factor substitution elasticity has a very small effect
(although its effect increases with a positive labor supply response).
Table 2. Percentage Increase in Income Available for Consumption: Sensitivity to
Labor Supply (λ) and Factor Substitution (S) Elasticities
Year λ = 0.2 S = 0.5 λ = 0.2, S = 0.5
1 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01
5 -0.07 -0.05 -0.08
10 -0.14 -0.11 -0.17
20 -0.34 -0.25 -0.40
Source: CRS calculations, see Appendix. Calculations assume E = 0.2 and, unless otherwise noted, λ = 0, S =
1.
Are there circumstances where the dividend relief plan can induce an increase in output? This
effect is more likely to occur when elasticities are positive and large, although even with very
large elasticities eventually the effect on output becomes negative. Another way to produce a
positive effect is to offset the relief plan with some offsetting spending reduction. Table 3
explores these effects, with some very high savings elasticities and assumptions that either offset
the deficit immediately, or offset the deficit after 10 years.
Higher elasticities can reduce the negative output effects, but only very large elasticities (clearly
far out of the range of empirical estimates) produce short-run positive effects (and these would
also produce contractionary effects for short-run stimulative purposes). Eventually the effects
would turn negative (even the elasticity of 3 has an effect that peaks at only 7/100 of 1% after
about 20 years and becomes negative after 50 years).
Table 3 also examines assumptions that the deficit will be offset by spending decreases, in one
case immediately and in the other after 10 years. Eliminating the deficit through a spending offset
would increase output, although the amount is likely to be small for reasonable elasticities.
Eliminating the deficit after ten years with an elasticity of 0.2, however, produces contractions in
output for 36 years.





Table 3. Percentage Increase in Income Available for Consumption, Effects of Large
Savings Elasticities (E) and Deficit Offsets via Spending Cuts
Year E = 1 E = 2 E = 3 No Deficit No Deficit After 10 Years
1 -0.00 0.00 0.01 0.00 -0.01
5 -0.03 0.01 0.04 0.00 -0.05
10 -0.05 0.01 0.06 0.03 -0.11
20 -0.13 -0.01 0.07 0.05 -0.06
Source: CRS calculations, see Appendix. Calculations assume fixed labor supply and factor substitution
elasticity of 1.0. Deficit offset simulations assume E = 0.2.
The negative effects on output could be offset if assumptions were made that foreign capital
inflows would finance the deficit in excess of private saving. Although imported capital can
prevent a decline in productivity, the returns to that investment are not available for domestic use.
The effects are also sensitive to the level of tax on the earnings of foreign capital. Table 4
provides estimates of the effect on standard of living (where foreigners have the claim to
earnings) in one case where no taxes apply to capital income from abroad and in the other case
when full taxes apply. The results are the same in direction and similar in magnitude to those
without capital imports.
Table 4. Percentage Increase in Income Available for Consumption,
Effects of International Capital Flows
Year No Capital Inflow Full Capital Inflow, Return Taxed Full Capital Income, Return Not Taxed
1 -0.01 -0.01 -0.01
5 -0.05 -0.05 -0.05
10 -0.11 -0.10 -0.10
20 -0.26 -0.21 -0.26
Source: CRS calculations, see Appendix.
The model used in this analysis is a simplified Solow growth model with an endogenous savings 5
rate which relies on reduced form empirical elasticities and assume myopia. There are also
models that are built up from consumers who maximize utility, and are forward looking; a model 6
that is currently in use is a life cycle model. Forward looking models cannot be solved at all

5 Reduced form estimates are derived from regressions of savings rates on observed returns (and other variables)a
reduced and simplified form of supply relationships that might be derived from an approach that begins with a utility
function for choosing between consumption across periods.
6 A related model is an infinite horizon model which treats the economy as a representative, infinitely lived individual.
This model would produce positive growth effects because it forces an infinite savings elasticity, but requires many
restrictive assumptions.





(even for the initial years) without taking some measures to address the budget deficit.7 Although
behavioral responses are derived from econometric studies, these models rely on many arbitrary
assumptions that could greatly alter the outcome (in particular, they tend to have large income
effects) and have generally not been empirically tested for reduced form effects.
The estimates from these modeling simulations show that capital income tax cuts, financed by
government deficits, induce negative effects on output in a full employment model, and that these
negative effects get larger over time. The initial effects in either direction are quite small,
reflecting the small size of the tax cuts and the slow adjustment of the capital stock. However,
even if the deficit effects are offset, under reasonable elasticities, these negative growth effects
appear for many years. When gains to future well-being are appropriately measured, such
negative effects cannot be avoided with foreign capital inflows. Nor is the negative effect an
artifact of the type of model: such effects would also occur with more sophisticated life cycle
models as well. Thus economic benefits of a debt-financed dividend relief proposal must be
sought elsewhere. The next section turns to the classic argument for corporate tax integration.

Dividend relief might or might not increase private savings, and it will contract the capital stock
if it is financed by debt, but it should also alter the allocation of savings from other uses into the
stock market. Capital may be withdrawn from debt (including tax exempt debt), investment in
unincorporated business, or in owner occupied housing. This induced allocation of savings has
certain effects, in the short run as well as the long run, that might be considered.
In the short run, the reallocation of assets could undermine the effects of the dividend relief
provision as a stimulus, if assets are moved from actual physical investment (such as investments
in housing, consumer durables, and unincorporated business assets). The reallocation of capital
out of debt and into equity, which would have the effect of raising interest rates, depressing bond
and housing prices, and increasing stock market values, could also undermine the stimulus effect
if firms are more sensitive to the effects of interest rates on their investment plans than they are to
stock prices.
In the long run, the reallocation of assets has important implications for two issues closely
associated with corporate tax relief: fairness and economic efficiency.
Although references have been made to the unfairness of the double tax, this argument is not
generally made by economists. A heavier tax on one type of investment leads to changes in
investor behavior (investors withdraw from the heavily taxed sector and invest in the more lightly
taxed sector). The result of this process is that after-tax returns (net of risk) are equated. Since
investors are free to invest in any type of asset, there is no inequity across taxpayers based merely
on where they invest. There is, however, inefficiency because heavily taxed assets must earn a
higher return before tax than lightly taxed investments.

7 See CRS Report RL32517, Distributional Effects of Taxes on Corporate Profits, Investment Income, and Estates, by
Jane G. Gravelle for a more detailed discussion of the issues surrounding savings responses.





The tax relief may be considered unfair by some from a vertical equity standpoint, because higher 8
income individuals receive more of the benefits from the tax cut. Moreover, merely changing a
tax provision actually induces some unfairness across current investors because it provides the
taxpayers holding the assets whose taxes are reduced (in this case, investments in stocks) with
windfall gains, and those holding disfavored assets with windfall losses. For dividend relief, these
windfall gains are captured in a stock market effect which is a subject for discussion below.
The classic economic argument for eliminating double taxation (or, more generally, integration of
corporate and individual income taxes) has always been efficiency. The current system creates a
number of economic distortions, causing too little capital to be allocated to the corporate sector,
debt ratios that are too high, and payout ratios that are too low. There is some dispute about the
magnitude of efficiency gains but Treasury, using a range of models and assumptions, estimated
gains that ranged from 0.11% to 0.53% of consumption, in a study of integration released in 9
1992. Most of these efficiency effects would not appear in actual output increases, but in a more
desirable allocation of consumer goods and a more efficient allocation of risk. However, these
improvements in welfare are represented as the equivalents of dollar increases in output and, at
2001 income levels, these amounts are between $8 billion and $37 billion. These projected
efficiency gains would take some period of time to occur, as the capital stock shifted between
sectors, but would eventually offset some of the negative effects of a diminished capital stock.
(They would be permanent effects, however, and would not prevent the eventually explosive
effects of continual deficits.)
These effects do not account for a specific aspect of the dividend proposal that decreases its cost
and may reduce the associated welfare gain, the limit on preferences discussed in the next section.


Two provisions limit the benefits—and the revenue loss—of the President’s approach to corporate
tax integration. First, the benefits are not available to tax-exempt shareholders (e.g., pension
funds) or foreign shareholders who do not pay U.S. individual income tax. Over half of 10
stockholders fall into this position. Secondly, in the original proposal there was a restriction on
benefits for income that is not subject to tax because of tax preferences, which probably reduced 11
the tax cuts by around a third. The final provision enacted was of a probably similar, perhaps

8 See CRS Report RL31597, The Taxation of Dividend Income: An Overview and Economic Analysis of the Issues, by
Gregg A. Esenwein and Jane G. Gravelle.
9 U.S. Department of the Treasury, Integration of the Individual and Corporate Income Tax Systems, Taxing Business
Income Once, Jan. 1992. The range represents differences in model assumptions about the substitutability of capital
between sectors and how revenue would be made up (through lump sum taxes or an overall increase in all capital gains
taxes). These effects would be smaller if atrapped equity or “new view of dividends is assumed, an issue that will
be discussed separately.
10 See CRS Report RL31597, The Taxation of Dividend Income: An Overview and Economic Analysis of the Issues, by
Gregg A. Esenwein and Jane G. Gravelle.
11 Tax expenditures are special deductions, exclusions and credits that are considered to department from a normal
income tax. In 2003, tax expenditures were about 65% of tax liability, implying about a 40% reduction in cost.
However, because of the stacking of dividend relief first, which is subject to higher taxes, the reduction in revenue cost
would be smaller (by as much as a half). Tax expenditures are a little higher than average currently because of
temporary expensing; however, the tax expenditure list may not include all subsidies.





slightly smaller, magnitude: it had no preference passthrough, but only partially cut the dividend
rate to 15% rather than eliminating the dividend tax (cutting the rate by slightly more than half for
top rate taxpayers). It also cut the capital gains tax rate.
These aspects introduce some uncertainty in general into the analysis of effects. For example, to
the extent that tax-exempt holdings are not marginal, the effect on savings would be larger
because the marginal effect would be larger than the average. It is unlikely however, that this
effect would reverse the conclusions that the proposal will be contractionary for growth. For
modeling purposes, if a term were added for an additional marginal tax rate effect that doubles its
size and a substitution elasticity of 1 plus the base elasticity were used in the growth model
discussed above (see discussion in Appendix), the effects, even for the highest value in Table 1,
would be negligible in the first few years and still eventually turn negative, reducing output by

0.02% in year 10, and by 0.21% in year 20.


Since tax exempt funds can make portfolio choices, there is less reason to adjust efficiency effects
discussed in the previous section or stock market effects to consider them infra-marginal.
The second provision originally in the President’s proposal would have restricted tax benefits for 12
income that is preferentially treated. It is always possible that such restrictions might be
reconsidered in future proposals. These provisions were designed to disallow dividend exclusions
and increases in basis for income that has not been subject to a tax. There are many implications
of these provisions. While these provisions would not drive a potential wedge between average
and marginal tax rates, as in the case of the tax exempt investors, they make the interpretation of
welfare gains more problematic. To the extent that they preserve differential treatment between
corporate and non-corporate investment, debt and equity, and payout functions compared to a
provision that did not limit tax benefits, they lower the welfare gains of corporate tax integration.
If they discourage activities that were desirable to encourage, the effect would also be to lower
welfare gains; however, if they discourage activities that were not desirable to encourage, the
effect would be to raise welfare gains. Whatever the net effect of the preference passthrough
provision, a better approach if preferences were viewed as undesirable would be to repeal them
outright, as this provision preserves the benefits for unincorporated business investment and debt
finance, but not for corporate equity investment.
These two aspects of the proposal might also have interacted. There are incentives for tax exempt
investors to shift to firms that have a lot of preferences and taxable investors to shift to firms with
few preferences, which could result in a larger tax cut and larger cost.

There has been considerable discussion of the effect of the dividend relief on the stock market.
Certainly the decline in the stock market during the time the proposal was formulated caused
losses to the financial assets of many individuals, although many observers believed that stock
values were overpriced and that the market would eventually have to decline. Some arguments
incorporate increasing investor or consumer confidence, which suggests a short-run stimulus
objective.

12 For an analysis of this provision see CRS Report RL31782, The Effect of the President’s Dividend Relief Proposal on
Corporate Tax Subsidies, by Gregg A. Esenwein and Jane G. Gravelle.





The stock market is subject to fluctuations, but its value is also an important price signal
mediating between investors and firms. To undertake a permanent tax change for the purpose of
influencing the stock market price is an objective not easy to justify—particularly since it cannot
be done a second time. The principal justification for focusing on this value is an expectation that
the rise in the stock market would spur spending in the short run.
Increases in stock market values are thought to increase spending through a wealth effect, 13
although both theory and empirical evidence suggest the wealth effect on consumption is small.
In theory, however, a rise in the stock market induced by tax cuts reflects the windfall gains that
accrue to investors who already hold an asset, and arise from the need for time to adjust portfolios
and capital stocks in response to the tax change. The rise is simply a manifestation of part of the
income effect that should already be considered in evaluating any economic stimulus and
therefore should not be considered as having a separate stimulative effect on the economy (unless
investors are not rational). If adjustment were instantaneous, the stock market’s value would
never change, at least under traditional views of dividends. The larger the stock market price
effect, the smaller the economic efficiency benefits to reallocating capital that are the principal
justification for corporate tax integration.
Moreover, the rise in the stock market does not simply appear by magic—it arises out of shifts in
supply and demand as do any other prices in the economy. If savings and portfolio allocations
were fixed, no changes in the value of the stock market would occur, and stockholders would
simply earn a higher rate of return. If the stock market does rise, it is also important to recognize
the processes that lead to that increase and their consequences for short-run effects on demand.
Individuals may be saving more (which is contractionary) or they may be shifting out of other
assets (which can be contractionary if coming from physical investment and raise interest rates if
coming from bonds). The rise in interest rates will contract investment spending financed from
debt. If corporate firms are to increase their equity investment, they must either retain more
earnings (which reduces dividends available for other spending) or they must increase the supply
of stock shares (by issuing stock or reducing repurchases). This increase in stock shares will push
stock prices back down somewhat and the increase in investment will ultimately drive down
returns per share.
It is possible that a rise in the stock market could result in an increase in business or consumer
confidence that could separately produce an economic stimulus. Some research in this area has
suggested that such an effect on consumers is not very likely, since the run up in the stock market
in the 1990s seemed to primarily manifest itself in the increased spending of higher income 14
individuals who own stock. Moreover, businesses, particularly sophisticated firms, would likely
be aware of the link between tax cuts and wealth. But, in any case, if there is a relationship it
presumably would depend on the magnitude of expected effects—they should be large enough to

13 See James M. Poterba, “Stock Market Wealth and Consumption,The Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 14,
spring 2000, pp. 99-118 for a review of the literature, which suggests a dollar of wealth increases consumption by about
3 cents.
14 A recent study by Karen Dynan and Dean Maki, “Does Stock Market Wealth Matter for Consumption? as well as a
study by Dean Maki and Michael Palumbo, “Distentangling the Wealth Effect: A Cohort Analysis of Household
Savings in the 1990s,” both in Finance and Economics Discussion Papers, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve,
2001-23, and 2001-21 respectively, found little or no relationship between stock market wealth and consumption by
those who did not own stock.





at least attract attention. The remainder of this section attempts to quantify the expected effect on
the stock market to determine whether it might be large enough to gain notice.
Perhaps the simplest way to explore this issue of the stock market effect is to discuss the
magnitude of potential effects that have been in the news and whether those effects are reasonable
and significant. This analysis will be followed by a brief explanation and discussion of the
implications of an alternative economic theory about the effect on stock market prices—the
trapped equity view.
When the dividend proposal was initially introduced, potential effects on the stock market of up 15
to 20%, which would be significant, were mentioned. Two other estimates of the effect: one
provided by the administration at 10%, and one estimated by MIT economist James Poterba, of 16
5% to 6%, were reported in a Wall Street Journal article. (The proposal also includes reductions
in capital gains taxes on income retained in the firm). This section examines the value of 5%-6%
proposed by Poterba (where underlying data are presented to support the calculation). The
analysis suggests that this value is probably an upper limit to the effect, and the likely effect
would be much less, perhaps no more than 1% or 2%. Certainly, the effect is likely to be small
compared to normal fluctuations in market values.
There are no explanations of the source of the 10% estimate, but Poterba provides the basics for
his calculation, which is a very straightforward estimate of the present value of the tax cut divided
by the value of the stock market. His calculation appears to be of the form:
% Change in Stock Value = Tax Cut
Discount
Stock Value
There are four issues that affect this percentage: the size of the tax cut, the discount factor, the
current value of the stock market, and whether the formula itself, which reflects a full and
permanent expected capitalization effect, is complete. We consider each factor in turn.
Poterba reports the first year tax cut as $26 billion. The Treasury estimate of the dividend tax
proposal is $20 billion for 2003, according to an Administration document issued on January 7,
2003. This number is, however, somewhat understated for capitalizing over time because the
proposal includes not only dividend relief but also a basis adjustment that will reduce tax revenue
later; only a small share of this basis adjustment is included in the first year cost. There may also
be some slight difference because of accruals versus collections. To correct for the first, the
estimated costs would increase to about $25 billion were the full effects of basis adjustment to be

15 See “Can a Dividend Tax Cut Juice Growth, Business Week Online, Jan. 3, 2003. The 20% number is attributed to
Glenn Hubbard, then Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisors, but that number probably reflects an analysis in
an academic research article reflecting the trapped equity, or “new view, discussed in the next section. An estimate of
6% to 9% was also mentioned in the Jan. 3 article.
16 Bob Davis and Greg Ip, “The If Factor: Bush Stimulus Package Needs Many Assumptions to Pan Out,Wall Street
Journal, Jan. 8, 2003, p.1.





taken into account.17 Given there is some slight discrepancy between accrual and collection basis
that would also make the Treasury number slightly too small, along with a small offsetting effect
from the fact that the first few years do not actually include the full effects of basis adjustment,
Poterba’s $26 billion number is a reasonable one.
The annual revenue cost must be summed over all future years and then discounted at some rate
of return in order to create a present value. Poterba estimates the present value of the stream of
tax cuts to be $500 billion to $650 billion. In a growing economy, one would normally think that
dividends and tax payments would grow at the growth rate of the economy as well as being
discounted at some after-tax equity return. Thus we can think of the discount factor as being R -
g, where R is the after tax required rate of return of the investor and g is the growth rate. The
difference between the two should also reflect the current after tax earnings as a percentage of
asset value. By working backward, we can determine this discount factor to be 0.04 (26/650) and 18

0.052 (26/500). This range of values is reasonable.


Estimates are sensitive to stock market value, which, of course, fluctuates considerably. At close 19
of business on January 15, the value was estimated at $12.2 trillion, which leads to a range of
percentage appreciation derived from the tax cut of about 4.1% to 5.3% using Poterba’s method.
Slightly over a week later on January 24, it had fallen to about $11.6 trillion. Poterba appears to
be using a value of around $10 trillion to $11 trillion which is lower than these values but
reasonable given the market’s volatility.
In any case, a 5% to 6% stock market gain from the tax proposal is a relatively small effect. For
example, for the slightly over three-month period from the end of September 2002 to mid-January
2003, the market rose by 12%, an effect over twice the size of the estimated stock market effect
of the dividend tax proposal. The market fell by 5% from January 15 to January 24, a period of

17 Based on an average five-year holding period, the current year cost for the basis adjustment’s effect on capital gains
will be about a fifth of the long-run effect. However, the capital gains tax is much lower than the dividend tax, so its
importance is somewhat diminished. Capital gains tax rates are around 18%. (Gains for those in the 15% bracket are
taxed at 10% if held for one year and 8% if held for five years; otherwise gains are taxed at 20% if held for one year
and 18% if held for 10 years.) If we cut the 18% rate in half to account for the fact that about half of gains are never
realized, and assume that the average marginal tax rate on ordinary income is around 30%, the capital gains tax rate is
about 30% of the individual rate. With about half of earnings paid out as dividends, based on data for the last few years,
the permanent cost will bear the ratio of (0.5X0.3+0.5)/(0.5X0.2X0.3+0.5), or 1.23. This ratio suggests a cost of $24.6
billion. (Note: When calculating dividend payout shares from the National Income and Product Accounts, it is
important to subtract out from earnings and from dividends the significant amount of dividends paid by Subchapter S
corporations that do not pay the corporate tax.) There may also be some slight difference because of accruals versus
collections.
18 One can use either real or nominal values. With a 2.5% real growth rate, the 4% value implies a real return of 6.5%
and a nominal return of 8% with 2.5% inflation. The 5.2% value implies a return of 7.7% real and 10.2% nominal
return with 2.5% inflation.
19 This value is based on market value at the end of the 3rd quarter 2002 for the Nasdaq, New York Stock Exchange and
Amex: $1.717 trillion, $9.041 trillion and $0.094 trillion respectively, or $10.8 trillion. These values were updated for
close of business January 15 using the Nasdaq, S&P 500 and the AMEX composite (factors of 1.215, 1.122, and 1
respectively, see http://finance.yahoo.com/m1?u; note that the NYSE composite was not used because it has been
recentered).





slightly over a week. This effect is about the same size as Poterba’s estimated stock market effect
and it suggests that if Poterba’s calculation is correct, the increased value is unlikely to have
much effect on consumer or investor confidence.
The calculated effect is the equivalent of permanently capitalizing the value of the tax cut in the 20
market. But there are two important reasons that this value is an upper limit.
The first, and perhaps most important, is that the higher returns in the stock market will attract
money out of the bond market, and raise interest rates. (The economic stimulus itself also
increases interest rates by increasing the demand for money.) This increase in interest rates will
have two effects that tend to lower the effect on the stock market. The most important is that the
expected after tax return that forms part of the discount factor is tied to interest rates and will rise.
Even very small increases could eliminate most of the expected rise in stock prices. For example,
a 10 basis point change in the interest rate, that increases it by 0.1%, would reduce market values 21
by 2 to 2.5%, and would offset about half the estimated rise in value. A change of slightly over
20 basis points would eliminate the effect completely even if this effect occurred only through the
discount factor. The higher interest rates will also, however, increase the cost of borrowing for
firms and reduce cash flow which would also act to reduce stock market values.
If the supply of savings is fixed (e.g. increased private savings does no more than offset
government borrowing to finance the tax cut), there is no new wealth in the economy. In that
case, asset prices in the economy will quickly return to their equilibrium values. As soon as
individuals make their portfolio shifts (out of bonds and into stocks), which would presumably
happen very quickly, the interest rate would rise. Moreover, some effect on corporate cash flow
would occur as borrowing costs rose. The offsetting of the price effect would appear more quickly
if individuals are forward-looking and expect interest rates to rise. That is, if individuals have
foresight and expect interest rates to rise, they will take this expectation into account and alter
their own discount rate for valuing stock immediately even before portfolio shifts are complete or
all debt has turned over.
If the savings rate increases, there could be a longer adjustment period but the rise in prices would
be temporary. That is because added investment would ultimately drive down the marginal return
on capital. If individuals are myopic, there could be a rise that will simply decline over time. But
if investors are rational and forward looking, the expected change itself would moderate the
initial rise. The Appendix shows how this adjustment process might occur when we hold the
interest rate fixed. If h is the fraction of the remaining difference between the new and old values
of the marginal product of capital that is made in each period, then the ratio of the actual
percentage change assuming forward looking investors to the change as calculated above is
discount/(discount+h) (as shown in the Appendix). In the case, for example, where the dividend
rate equals .04 and the fully capitalized effect is 5.3%, if h = 0.10, the actual effect will be only

20 Under one theory about markets, mainly that dividend taxes in excess of capital gains taxes, are capitalized into asset
values, there is a permanent rise in the stock market from repealing the dividend tax. This view, referred to as the
trapped equity view and also thenew view,” (as opposed to the traditional view) suggests that dividend taxes do not
matter to investment behavior and will be discussed below.
21 The ratio of new to old market value is (R-g)(R-g+0.1), where R-g is the discount factor. Thus the price falls by 2.5
% at 4% (1-.04/.041) and by 1.9% at 5.2% (1-.052/.053). This calculation assumes an additive risk premium.





1.5%. Since the effect of this change on the desired capital stock and the desired marginal product
of capital is only about 4 or 5%, this change is a small one that could be expected to be adjusted
to quickly.
There is one offsetting factor that could lead to a small share of the market rise being permanent:
the possibility of permanent excess profits from market power. If a firm is earning excess profits
because it has market (or monopoly) power, that effect would have been capitalized into a higher
market value for stocks. To use an extreme case, if every firm were a pure monopoly with
demand characterized by a linear demand curve, only half of a change in tax is passed on in price.
Therefore, one would expect that if the only adjustment that occurred was a change in the
marginal product of capital, half the rise in the stock market would be permanent and, using the
example in the previous paragraph, the initial effect might be a 3% increase rather than a 1.5%
increase. This effect is much too large, however. Some of the adjustment is likely to take place in
the discount rate in the denominator, which exerts the same proportional effect regardless of
market value. Pure (unregulated) monopolies largely don’t exist in the United States, and the
passthrough becomes larger as the number of firms increase. Moreover, in oligopoly models of
any size, price competition (known as Bertrand competition) can lead to the same effects as
perfect competition. Thus, while the effects of market power are likely to slightly increase the
initial price effect because some effects are permanent, this effect is probably quite small.
There is a theory, referred to as the “trapped equity” or “new” view (although it is 25 years old)
that suggests dividend taxes (in excess of capital gains taxes) are irrelevant to investment
behavior. The entire stream of dividend taxes in excess of capital gains taxes under the proposal
would show up as a windfall to current stockholders. If one holds this view, the effects on the
stock market should be larger. However, there would be little efficiency gain from the reallocation
of capital for eliminating these taxes. Again, a belief in a large permanent effect on the stock
market is only consistent with a belief that there is little to gain in efficiency effects from
dividend tax relief. As this section suggests, however, even this analysis suggests a stock market
increase of only 3%.
For a tax that reduces both dividends and capital gains taxes, the portion that reflects the excess of
dividends over capital gains would be permanently capitalized. Assuming a tax rate of 30% on
dividends and 10% on capital gains, and about half of income paid in each form, about half the
tax cut would be permanently capitalized. To understand how this theory developed and what it
means, it helps to contrast it with the traditional view, which underlies the analysis in the previous
section.
In the traditional view of dividends the cost of capital is affected by both the dividend and capital
gains tax rates. The double tax on dividends causes inefficiencies and misallocation of capital
away from corporate equity investment. In the new view, the dividend tax has no effect on
investment (see Appendix for a mathematical derivation of this effect).
In the traditional view, with perfect competition and without other tax subsidies, the value of a
dollar of equity owned capital is equal to a dollar of value in the stock market. While stock
market prices may rise initially, they will eventually return to this equilibrium value as discussed
above and expectations will limit the initial rise. In the trapped equity view, dividend taxes (in
excess of capital gains taxes), which do not influence investment, are windfall losses to the
individuals who own stock when the dividend tax is imposed and are expressed in a permanent





reduction in stock price. Removal of those taxes would be a windfall loss to current owners. (The
actual supply and demand processes that accompany this effect are not clear.)
One of the issues that spurred the development of the trapped equity theory was the fact that firms
pay dividends, even though they are more heavily taxed than capital gains. To explain why firms
pay dividends, the traditional view of dividends requires that dividends have some value or be
differentiated in some way from capital gains; otherwise firms would never pay dividends and
would distribute excess earnings by repurchasing stock. Several economic theories could
motivate the payment of dividends. The simplest is that dividend and capital gains income differ
in important ways (earnings from sales of assets fluctuate more and involve greater transactions
costs than the receipt of dividends). Economists have also advanced notions dealing with
imperfect information (dividends are a signal that the firm is doing well) and principal agent
problems (dividends keep managers from diverting or wasting too much of the earnings).
The original form of the trapped equity view was essentially an alternative way of explaining why
firms pay dividends. It is based on the notion that dividends are trapped in the firm and that
earnings cannot be paid out to the shareholder in any other form (i.e., no share repurchases). The
dividend tax must be paid now, or later with interest, but cannot be avoided. The idea is much like
an that associated with an individual retirement account. The problem of double taxation is much
less severe because the cost of capital is affected only by the accrual equivalent capital gains tax
rate which tends to be small because of lower rates, deferral of tax, and avoidance of tax if held
until death.
Assuming financing via retained earnings, in the new view a dollar of equity capital has a value
(referred to as q) of (1-θ)/(1-c), where θ is the dividend tax rate and c is the capital gain tax rate.
This ratio occurs because the shareholder is indifferent between receiving a dollar of dividends
net of tax (that is the cost of retaining earnings is (1-θ)) and retaining it in the firm where its value
is the increase in value, or q, times (1-c), where c is the capital gains tax rate.
This formula may explain how some of the larger effects that might be expected on stock market
values might have been calculated if dividend relief was provided. For example, if the dividend
rate is 30% and the accrual equivalent capital gains tax is 10% (an estimate that is consistent with
evidence suggesting that close to half of capital gains are never taxed), the value of the stock
market is (1-0.3)/(1-0.1), or $0.78 for each dollar of capital. Eliminating both taxes (or reducing
the dividend tax to 0.2) would permanently increase the value to $1 or almost 30% and thus it
may not be surprising if the finding of evidence for the new view in academic research might
have lead to the conclusion of a 20% stock market effect.
These estimates are, however, likely to be overstated, because a large fraction of taxpayers (more
than half) are not subject to taxes on dividends. If a weighted average is used, the tax rates would
be only about 40% as large, so the effect on the stock market would be closer to 9% (rising from
(1-0.4X0.3)/(1-0.4X0.1) or $0.917 to $1). In the actual proposal, of course, dividend taxes would
not be eliminated but would remain to the extent of preferences. If preferences reduce the tax cut
by a third, the new value would be (1-0.4X0.3X0.67)/(1-0.4X0.1X0.67) or $0.945, implying only
a 3% increase.
The trapped equity view, at least in its pure original form, has fallen out of favor somewhat for
theoretical reasons. One of the requirements for this pure form is that firms not be able to
repurchase their own shares, an option that has always been available in the United States, and in
fact has increasingly been used by firms. Another is that firms do not issue shares and pay





dividends simultaneously. The traditional view can easily accommodate the repurchase of shares
along with payment of dividends, while modifications to the new view to make it consistent with
observed share repurchases may succeed in maintaining the view that dividends are irrelevant to
investment but tend to reduce the magnitude of the stock market effects. One such approach is to
make the dividend tax rate in the valuation formula a weighted average of the dividend tax and
the capital gains tax based on the ratios of dividends paid to share repurchases although even this
view requires a quite restrictive assumption of a fixed proportion of repurchases and dividends.
There are some other conceptual problems that arise with the trapped equity view as well as a 22
number of attempts to address the issue through empirical studies.


After the dividend tax reduction was enacted in the second quarter of 2003, a subsequent report 23
by the American Council for Capital Formation (hereafter the ACCF report) cited evidence on
the effect on dividend payouts and savings of the reduction. The report referred in turn to two 24
recent papers, one a study by Raj Chetty and Emmanuel Saez (hereafter the Chetty-Saez study), 25
the other released by the Securities Industry Association (hereafter SIA report). The ACCF
report argues that the evidence in these two studies shows that corporations increased dividend
payments in response to the rate cut and that this response should stimulate more savings and
investment.
This section discusses two issues. The first is the evidence on the effect of the tax cut on dividend
payments. The second is the implication of this evidence for savings rates.
As discussed below, the evidence from the recent updates of the National Income and Product
Accounts (NIPA) does not appear to support a significant response of dividend payouts to the
dividend tax cut. Even they it did, however, there is no reason to connect that dividend cut to
savings and growth. Indeed, as discussed above, it appears unlikely that a dividend tax cut
financed by a deficit increased saving in the economy. The most certain route to increasing saving
is probably to reduce the deficit.

22 For an earlier and non-mathematical survey of this issue, see George Zodrow, “On theTraditional” and “New
Views of Dividend Taxation, National Tax Journal, vol. 44, part 2, Dec. 1991, pp. 497. This paper suggests that the
empirical work has not supported the new view. Three recent papers are Trevor S. Harris, R. Glenn Hubbard, and Dean
Kemsley, “The Share Price Effects of Dividend Taxes and Tax Imputation Credits,” NBER Working Paper 7445, Dec.
1999; Alan J. Auerbach and Kevin Hassett, “On the Marginal Source of Investment Funds,” Journal of Public
Economics, v. 87, Jan. 2003, pp. 205-232; and Michelle Hanlon, James N. Myers, and Terry Shevlon, “Dividend Taxes
and Firm Valuation,” Working Paper, University of Washington, July 11, 2002. The first two of these three more recent
papers are new empirical studies, both providing some support for the new view. The latter is essentially a criticism of
the methods used in the first of the three papers, but also contains a general review of the literature.
23 American Council for Capital Formation Special Report,Do Dividend Payments Respond to Tax Cuts? Does it
Really Matter? by Margo Thorning, Aug. 2004.
24 Raj Chetty and Emmanuel Saez, “Do Dividend Payments Respond to Taxes? Preliminary Evidence from the 2003
Dividend Tax Cut,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 10572, June 2004.
25 Securities Industry Association, Dividend Tax Cuts Deemed Effective, by Frank A. Fernandez, SIA Research
Reports, Vol. V, No. 8, Aug. 2, 2004.





The Chetty-Saez study used a sample of firms from the Center for Research on Securities Prices st
to examine dividends paid through the 1 quarter of 2004. While the authors found an increase in
dividends paid, they did not find the increase statistically significant (i.e. could not determine that
the increase was not due to chance), primarily because a few firms in their sample greatly
influenced the level of dividends. They did find a statistically significant increase in the number
of firms initiating the payment of dividends.
The SIA report does not provide a statistical analysis. The author reports evidence from Standard
and Poor’s Dividend Record that indicates an increase in the number of firms paying dividends,
and also reports results from the Chetty-Saez study. Finally, the author reports data identified as
being from the NIPA that appear to show a significant rise in personal dividend income. However,
we are not able to determine the source of the data in this table or the methodology used to
project data for quarters that have not yet occurred. At any rate, while this table appears to show a
rise in dividends, particularly at the end of 2004, the NIPA data do not show such a rise.
Table 5 shows personal dividend income from the NIPA. Aggregate dividends did not rise at all
in 2003, whether one is comparing the quarter when the proposal was announced in January 2003 st
(from 4th quarter 2002 to 1 quarter 2003) or the quarter after enactment (from 2nd quarter to 3rd
quarter 2003).
Table 5. Personal Dividend Income
Year and Quarter Personal Dividend Income ($ billions)
2002
- Q1 376.6
- Q2 387.1
- Q3 393.2
- Q4 394.6
2003
- Q1 393.5
- Q2 392.3
- Q3 391.6
- Q4 393.8
2004
- Q1 400.9
- Q2 410.6
Source: National Income and Product Accounts, Interactive Tables, February 2004: http://www.bea.doc.gov/bea/
dn/nipaweb/TableView.asp?SelectedTable=58&FirstYear=2002&LastYear=2004&Freq=Qtr.
Dividends did rise at the end of 2004 (to $432.3 billion in the third quarter and $531.4 billion in
the fourth), but this effect was well after the relief proposal was enacted. These data were not
available at the time of the studies, however.





These data do not suggest a surge in dividends, although it is always difficult to isolate a single 26
factor in time series analysis. These data also suggest that the sample used by Chetty and Saez
may not be representative. For example, in the Chetty-Saez report dividends rose in their sample th
from $26 billion in the 4 quarter of 2002 to $29 billion in the fourth quarter of 2003, a rise of

11%. The aggregate data indicate no change.


Not only did dividends grow very little, but they grew more slowly than nominal output and ndnd
much more slowly than corporate profits. From the 2 quarter of 2003 to the 2 quarter of 2004,
output grew by 6.97%, while dividends grew at 4.74%. Corporate profits grew considerably faster
(at 18%) than the economy in general. This effect—corporate profits growing faster at this point
in the business cycle—is not unusual. But it does suggest that the dividend payout ratio fell,
rather than rose, during that time.
The Chetty-Saez study was aimed at finding empirical evidence regarding the two competing
views of dividends. To recap, the traditional view is that the dividend tax affects investment in the
corporate sector, and that a cut in the dividend tax would change the return to investment—setting
into motion a variety of potential behavioral effects. The “new view” or “trapped equity” view, 27
argues that the dividend tax has no effect on investment: the tax is capitalized into asset values.
In that view, the dividend tax cut provides nothing more than a windfall gain for existing holders
of stock—and the central issue then becomes a distributional one.
The argument made in these reports (in varying degrees) is that evidence for the traditional view
means that the dividend cut would increase dividend payout shares, divert investment into the
corporate sector, and increase savings.
As suggested above, the empirical evidence for an increase in dividends in response to the tax cut 28
seems weak (although one can make a case for the traditional view on other grounds). But even
had dividends increased, one cannot necessarily ascribe that increase to the tax effects of the
traditional view, since dividends can increase in the “new view” if profits rise more quickly than
investment opportunities, an effect that could occur in business cycles.
But more importantly, finding support for the traditional view does not mean that the tax cut
increased savings. There are two possible reasons for this result. First, if firms pay out more
dividends, then individuals might consume rather than invest them. Much depends on whether
one views stockholders as “seeing through the corporate veil” and recognizing the increase in
dividends as tax induced.

26 Note that the dividend series in the NIPA include profits of Subchapter S corporations (firms that are incorporated,
but taxed as partnerships). However, these profits should be growing, both because of a time trend, and also because
profits in general are rising during this period. So this factor is unlikely to account for the flat dividend performance
during this period.
27 For a more complete explanation of thenew view versus thetraditional view see the discussion in CRS Report
RL31824, Dividend Tax Relief: Effects on Economic Recovery, Long-Term Growth, and the Stock Market, by Jane G.
Gravelle.
28 Ibid.





Secondly, as noted above, even if investors are perfectly rational and recognize the tax induced
payout, and even though the change might shift investment out of owner-occupied housing and
smaller unincorporated businesses to corporate firms (a gain in efficiency), the total capital stock
may not increase. That is, while the traditional view is necessary, in theory, to lead to an increase
in savings, it is not sufficient. While, according to theory, a dividend cut under the “new view”
should unambiguously decrease savings, a dividend cut under the “traditional view” could either
increase or decrease savings. That ambiguity arises from two sources mentioned previously, the
income and substitution effects, and, as noted in the section on growth, the effects would also
depend on how the tax savings were offset..
In sum, it is not clear that dividends increased in response to the tax cut, and whether they did or
did not, private savings may or may not have increased.

None of the effects of the dividend tax relief proposal are likely to be large, mainly because the
tax cut itself, since it is restricted to individual taxes and does not include tax exempt investors. It
amounts on average to about a one percentage point reduction in the overall tax rate on capital
income and about two percentage points in reduction of the tax on corporate equity. As a short-
term stimulus, either directly or via stock market effects (which are themselves quite small), it is
not clear that the dividend relief is superior to other alternatives, while its long-run growth effects
are negative if it is deficit financed (and may be negative even if it is not). The principal
economic justification for the proposal is the economic efficiency gains from more efficient
allocation of capital.






The growth model used to calculate the effect of dividend relief on future output and the standard
of living is composed of the following equations. The first is a production function:
(11/ ) (1/(11/ )) (1/(11/ ))(1) [ (1 ) ]S SStt tQAaK aL−−=+−
where Qt is output at time t, Kt is the capital stock at time t, Lt is the labor supply at time t, S is
the factor substitution elasticity, and A and a are constants.
The second is the equation for change in the capital stock letting all variables be expressed in
period 1 income levels:
[ (()](2) t ttktt tttt tts QKtRKtQKRK nKDKK δδ−− −−− −−−=
1 (1 )tt n+ +
where s is the savings rate out of disposable income, δ is the economic depreciation rate, tk is the
tax rate on capital income, R is the pretax rate of return to capital, t is the tax rate on labor
income, n is the growth rate of the economy, and D is the deficit which is the sum of tax change
and interest on the accumulated debt (pre-existing debt and deficit are set to zero). Interest on the
debt is the pretax return less a fixed 4% risk premiums, all multiplied by (1-tg) where t is the tax
rate on government interest payments.
The third is the equation for the savings rate:
(3) ( (1 ) ) Ettks bR t=−
where E is the savings elasticity and b is a constant.
Maximizing (1), subject to Qt = (Rt+δ)Kt + WtLt results in the first order condition:
1 1( (1 ))S StQ
(4) ( )tRa AK δ=−
t
The model is calibrated to resemble the U.S. economy, with initial W and Q normalized to 1, K
set at 3.5, δ set at 0.03, R set at .07, all initial tax rates set at 0.3, and n set at 0.025. The budget
constraint is used to calibrate labor supply, which is thereafter set as a fixed amount (not sensitive 29
to changes in the wage, which is a reasonable representation of the labor supply literature). We
do, however, explore the effects of a labor supply response, using the additional labor supply
formula:

29 Most evidence shows little or no response of labor supply to changes in the wage rate.





(5) ( (1 ) )ttL hW t γ=−
where h is a constant and γ is the labor supply elasticity.
We simulate the effects for a change similar in size to the proposed dividend relief plan
(determined by dividing initial revenue loss by output), reducing the tax rate on capital by one
percentage point.
For the discussion of using a larger versus marginal tax rate when considering tax exempt E*
investors, the savings equation in (2) above would be multiplied by a term that is [(1-ta)/(1-tm)],
where a and m refer to average and marginal tax rates, and E* to the substitution elasticity. The
substitution elasticity would be the observed elasticity plus the income elasticity.
In the case of international capital flows, the capital stock and output are fixed. The deficit still
accumulates and the effects on the standard of living are reflecting in a reduction of income
available to Americans because a share of the capital stock is owned by foreigners. Where this
return is subject to tax, some portion is available because it is collected by the Treasury.
This section discusses an approximation of the calculation of the effects if expected adjustment in
the stock market by forward looking investors. The effects do not account for the possible
speedup in capital gains taxes due to the rise and then fall of the price, but this effect is likely to
be small.
For investment purposes, one can solve for the marginal product of capital through an equation
for the present value of earnings on a dollar of investment:
()( 6) 1 { [ (1 ) ( ) ( )](1 ) } (1 )RgtMPK g z g cg e d t zµ δ µ δθ µ θ −−=−−++− +−
0
where MPK is the marginal product of capital, µ is the corporate tax rate, δ is the economic
depreciation rate, g is the growth rate, θ is the dividend tax rate, R is the after-tax discount rate,
and c is the capital gains tax rate. Solving for MPK, and assuming that economic depreciation is
allowed, so that z = δ/(R+δ)
())(7 ) Rg cMPK θ δ−−=+
(1 ) 1 )θµ−−
To solve for the value of the firm per dollar of capital stock:
()(8) { [ (1 ) ( ) ] (1 ) } RgtV MPK g D cg e dtµδµθ −−=−−+−
0
where V is the value of the firm and is the annual depreciation deduction. The solution to the
integral is {MPK(1-µ)-(g+δ) +µD](1-θ) - cg}/(R-g). Note, as discussed above, that an increase in
R will reduce the value. In the steady state, and assuming economic depreciation (D = δ) then, by
substituting (7) into (8), obtain V =1.





Eliminating the capital gains tax and the dividend tax, the value of the firm is:
()(9 ) [ (1 ) ( ) ] RgtV MP K g D e d tµδµ −−=−−+=
0
If the marginal product of capital never changes (permanent capitalization), then substituting (7)
into (9):
( ())R gcgθ −+
(1 )(10) 1V θ−=+
()Rg−
Allowing the marginal product to gradually fall to its new level:
()(1 1) * RgMPK δ−=+
(1 )µ−
Suppose the gap between old and new marginal product is expected to change at the rate h. Then
write the value as:
()(12) [( * ( *) (1 ) ( ) ]ht R g tV MPK MPK MPK e g D e dtµδµ −−=+−−+
0
When t is zero, the marginal product is equal to MPK; as t goes to infinity, the marginal product is
equal to MPK*.
( ())R gcgθ −+
(1 )(1 3 ) 1V θ−=+
()Rhg+−
Thus the ratio of change with the expectation of adjustment to the permanent capitalization effect
is (R-g)/(R+h-g). Note that we do not use (10) and (13) directly to determine stock values for two
reasons. First, we don’t have enough information about the effective tax rate given that only part
of dividends will be excluded because of preference allocation and only part of dividends are now
subject to tax. Second, these formulas for stock market effects would be true only if the market is
currently experiencing an equilibrium long-run price level under current tax rules, an assumption
that cannot be made. By using ratios, the estimate can be made with direct estimates of the value
of taxes and the stock market.
Assuming financing via retained earnings, a dollar of equity capital has a value of (1-θ)/(1-c).
This occurs because the shareholder is indifferent between receiving a dollar of dividends net of
tax (that is the cost of retaining earnings is (1-θ)) and retaining it in the firm where its value is the
increase in value, or q, times (1-c), where c is the capital gains tax rate. That is, in equilibrium





(1 )(14) (1 ) (1 ),q c and ther efore q θθ −−= − =
(1)c−
The present value of earnings on a dollar of capital must equal q. Therefore:
()(15) {[ (1)()()](1) } (1)RgtqMPK gzg qcgedzµ δ µ δθ µ θ −−=−−++− +−
0
and substituting in for the equilibrium value of q:
R
(16)MPKδ=+
(1 ) (1 )c µ−−
Only the capital gains tax rate appears in the marginal product of capital term.
Note that this model (as shown in equation (14)) implies perfect substitutability between
receiving earnings as a dividend and as a capital gain and dividends are paid out only as a residual
after all investment needs are satisfied. Note also that the model no longer works if share
repurchase is allowed as an alternative, which would imply that the earnings of share repurchase,
(1-c), equals the benefits of reinvestment, q(1-c). In this case, q would have to equal 1. Moreover,
no dividends would be paid. To allow for simultaneous investment, share repurchase, and
dividends a model that provides imperfect substitutions between these choices or some additional
benefit of dividends or cost of share repurchases. One such theory consistent with a traditional
view is that dividends are differentiated from capital gains so that for the marginal dollar the
dividend (and its benefit) or the capital gains (and its cost) are equated. Other theories have
presupposed that there is a fixed share of dividends and retained earnings (with all marginal
adjustments made through share issues) which is consistent with a traditional view, while another
is that share repurchases and dividends are made in fixed proportion (a theory consistent with a
modified new view where dividend taxes do not matter in the cost of capital and the value of θ is
a weighted average of the dividend and capital gains tax). Why such choices should be
completely imperfect substitutes is not clear, however. Theories also suppose that repurchasing
shares is costly relative to paying dividends because of information asymmetries which again
would permit a modified new view.
Jane G. Gravelle
Senior Specialist in Economic Policy
jgravelle@crs.loc.gov, 7-7829